Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-c47g7 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-23T16:33:55.488Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Conservation and employment creation: can privatizing natural resources benefit traditional users?

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  29 January 2013

Jean-Marie Baland
Affiliation:
CRED, University of Namur, Belgium. E-mail: jean-marie.baland@fundp.ac.be
Kjetil Bjorvatn
Affiliation:
NHH Norwegian School of Economics, Department of Economics, Helleveien 30, 5045 Bergen, Norway. Tel: +47 55 95 95 85. Fax: +47 55 95 95 43. E-mail: Kjetil.Bjorvatn@nhh.no

Abstract

The establishment of a private property regime is often proposed as a solution to the degradation of natural resources. While arguably more efficient than open access, private property often comes at a distributional cost (Weitzman, M. (1974), ‘Free access vs private ownership as alternative systems for managing common property’, Journal of Economic Theory 8(2): 225–234) as traditional users of the resource lose income and employment in the process. The present paper demonstrates that, in the case of renewable resources, traditional users may gain from privatization even if they are denied ownership of the resource. Indeed, a private owner maximizing profits tends to preserve the resource, which results in long-term increases in employment. We derive the conditions under which these long-term gains more than compensate traditional users for the short-run fall in labor demand and resource rents.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2013

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Baland, J.-M. and Francois, P. (2005), ‘Commons as insurance and the welfare impact of privatization’, Journal of Public Economics 89 (2–3): 211231.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baland, J.-M. and Platteau, J.-P. (1996), Halting Degradation of Natural Resources: Is There a Role for Rural Communities?, Oxford, UK Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Brito, D., Intriligator, M., and Sheshinski, E. (1997), ‘Privatization and the distribution of income in the commons’, Journal of Public Economics 64(2): 181205.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
de Meza, D. and Gould, J. (1985), ‘Free access vs private ownership: a comparison’, Journal of Economic Theory 36(2): 387391.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
de Meza, D. and Gould, J. (1987), ‘Free access versus private property in a resource: income distributions compared’, Journal of Political Economy 95(6): 1317–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diamond, J. (2005), Collapse: How Societies Choose to Fail or Survive, Penguin Books.Google Scholar
Hartwick, J. (1980), ‘The intertemporal externality in the dynamic common property renewable resource problem’, Economics Letters 5(1): 275280.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laurent-Lucchetti, J. and Santugini, M. (2012), ‘Ownership risk and the use of common-pool natural resources’, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 63(2): 242259.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ostrom, E. (1990), Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action, Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roe, D., Nelson, F., and Sandbrook, C. (eds) (2009), Community Management of Natural Resources in Africa: Impacts, Experiences and Future Directions, London: UK International Institute for Environment and Development.Google Scholar
Roemer, J. and Sylvestre, J. (1993), ‘The proportional solution for economies with both private and public ownership’, Journal of Economic Theory 59(2): 426444.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, P.A. (1974) ‘Is the rent collector worthy of his full hire?’, Eastern Economic Journal 1(1): 17.Google Scholar
Weitzman, M. (1974) ‘Free access vs private ownership as alternative systems for managing common property’, Journal of Economic Theory 8(2): 225234.CrossRefGoogle Scholar