Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-xtgtn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-18T11:48:04.444Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Military Coercion in Interstate Crises

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  31 October 2005

BRANISLAV L. SLANTCHEV
Affiliation:
University of California–San Diego

Abstract

Military mobilization simultaneously sinks costs, because it must be paid for regardless of the outcome, and ties hands, because it increases the probability of winning should war occur. Existing studies neglect this dualism and cannot explain signaling behavior and tacit bargaining well. I present a formal model that incorporates both functions and shows that many existing conclusions about crisis escalation have to be qualified. Contrary to models with either pure sunk costs or tying-hands signaling, bluffing is possible in equilibrium. General monotonicity results that relate the probability of war to an informed player's expected payoff from fighting do not extend to this environment with its endogenous distribution of power. Peace may involve higher military allocations than war. Rational deterrence models also assume that a commitment either does or does not exist. Extending these, I show how the military instrument can create commitments and investigate the difficulties with communicating them.

Type
ARTICLES
Copyright
© 2005 by the American Political Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Austen-Smith David, and Jeffrey S. Banks. 2000. “Cheap Talk and Burned Money.” Journal of Economic Theory 91 (1): 116.Google Scholar
Banks Jeffrey S. 1990. “Equilibrium Behavior in Crisis Bargaining Games.” American Journal of Political Science 34 (August): 599614.Google Scholar
Banks Jeffrey S., and Joel Sobel. 1987. “Equilibrium Selection in Signaling Games.” Econometrica 55 (May): 64761.Google Scholar
Brito Dagobert L., and Michael D. Intriligator. 1985. “Conflict, War, and Redistribution.” American Political Science Review 79 (December): 94357.Google Scholar
Brodie Bernard. 1959. Strategy in the Missile Age. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Cho In-Koo, and David M. Kreps. 1987. “Signaling Games and Stable Equilibria.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 102 (May): 179221.Google Scholar
Crawford Vincent P., and Joel Sobel. 1982. “Strategic Information Transmission.” Econometrica 50 (November): 143151.Google Scholar
Fearon James D. 1994. “Domestic Political Audiences and the Escalation of Internationl Disputes.” American Political Science Review 88 (September): 57792.Google Scholar
Fearon James D. 1995. “Rationalist Explanations for War.” International Organization 49 (Summer): 379414.Google Scholar
Fearon James D. 1997. “Signaling Foreign Policy Interests: Tying Hands versus Sinking Costs.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 41 (February): 6890.Google Scholar
Fudenberg Drew, and Jean Tirole. 1991. “Perfect Bayesian and Sequential Equilibrium.” Journal of Economic Theory 53 (2): 23660.Google Scholar
Grossman Sanford J., and Motty Perry. 1986. “Perfect Sequential Equilibrium.” Journal of Economic Theory 39: 97119.Google Scholar
Guisinger Alexandra, and Alastair Smith. 2002. “Honest Threats: The Interaction of Reputation and Political Institutions in International Crises.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 46 (April): 175200.Google Scholar
Hirshleifer Jack. 1988. “The Analytics of Continuing Conflict.” Synthese 76 (August): 20133.Google Scholar
Huth Paul K. 1988. Extended Deterrence and the Prevention of War. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Iklé Fred Charles. 1964. How Nations Negotiate. New York: Harper & Row.
Jervis Robert. 1970. The Logic of Images in International Relations. New York: Columbia University Press.
Jervis Robert. 1978. “Cooperation under the Security Dilemma.” World Politics 30 (January): 167214.Google Scholar
Kydd Andrew. 2000. “Arms Races and Arms Control: Modeling the Hawk Perspective.” American Journal of Political Science 44 (April): 22238.Google Scholar
Morrow James D. 1989. “Capabilities, Uncertainty, and Resolve: A Limited Information Model of Crisis Bargaining.” American Journal of Political Science 33 (November): 94172.Google Scholar
Morrow James D. 1994a. “Alliances, Credibility, and Peacetime Costs.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 38 (2): 27097.Google Scholar
Morrow James D. 1994b. “Modeling the Forms of International Cooperation: Distribution versus Information.” International Organization 48 (Summer): 387423.Google Scholar
O'Neill Barry. 1991. “Conflictual Moves in Bargaining: Warnings, Threats, Escalations, and Ultimatums.” In Negotiation Analysis, ed. H. Peyton Young. Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press. Chapter 5.
Powell Robert. 1990. Nuclear Deterrence Theory: The Search for Credibility. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Powell Robert. 1993. “Guns, Butter, and Anarchy.” American Political Science Review 87 (March): 11532.Google Scholar
Powell Robert. 1999. In the Shadow of Power. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Powell Robert. 2004. “The Inefficient Use of Power: Costly Conflict with Complete Information.” American Political Science Review 98 (May): 23141.Google Scholar
Quester George. 1977. Offense and Defense in the International System. New York: Wiley.
Rector Chad. 2003. “Getting There is Half the Battle: How Military Mobilization Costs Influence Crisis Bargaining.” Presented at the 2003 Meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association. Chicago IL.
Sartori Anne E. 2002. “The Might of the Pen: A Reputational Theory of Communication in International Disputes.” International Organization 56 (February): 12149.Google Scholar
Schelling Thomas C. 1960. The Strategy of Conflict. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Schelling Thomas C. 1966. Arms and Influence. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Schultz Kenneth A. 2001a. Democracy and Coercive Diplomacy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Schultz Kenneth A. 2001b. “Looking for Audience Costs.” The Journal of Conflict Resolution 45 (February): 3260.Google Scholar
Signorino Curtis S., and Ahmer Tarar. 1999. “A Unified Theory and Test of Extended Immediate Deterrence.” Presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Washington, DC.
Slantchev Branislav L. 2003. “The Principle of Convergence in Wartime Negotiations.” American Political Science Review 47 (December): 62132.Google Scholar
Slantchev Branislav L. 2004a. “Mobilization, Offense Dominance, and Preemptive War.” University of California, San Diego. Manuscript.
Slantchev Branislav L. N.d.Politicians, the Media, and Domestic Audience Costs.” International Studies Quarterly. Forthcoming.
Smith Alastair. 1998. “International Crises and Domestic Politics.” American Political Science Review 92 (3): 62338.Google Scholar
Spence Michael. 1973. “Job Market Signaling.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 87 (August): 35574.Google Scholar
Strachan Hew. 2003. The First World War. New York: Viking.
Zagare Frank C., and D. Marc Kilgour. 2000. Perfect Deterrence. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.