Hostname: page-component-7c8c6479df-r7xzm Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-03-28T03:09:10.080Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

How to Promote Order and Property Rights under Weak Rule of Law? An Experiment in Changing Dispute Resolution Behavior through Community Education

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  04 February 2014

CHRISTOPHER BLATTMAN*
Affiliation:
Columbia University
ALEXANDRA C. HARTMAN*
Affiliation:
Yale University
ROBERT A. BLAIR*
Affiliation:
Yale University
*
Christopher Blattman is Assistant Professor of Political Science and International Affairs, Columbia University, Department of Politics & SIPA, 420 W 118th St, New York, NY 10027, (chrisblattman@columbia.edu)
Alexandra C. Hartman is Ph.D. candidate in Political Science, Yale University, Department of Political Science, 115 Prospect Street, New Haven, CT 06520, (alexandra.hartman@yale.edu)
Robert A. Blair is Ph.D. candidate in Political Science, Yale University, Department of Political Science, 115 Prospect Street, New Haven, CT 06520, (robert.blair@yale.edu).

Abstract

Dispute resolution institutions facilitate agreements and preserve the peace whenever property rights are imperfect. In weak states, strengthening formal institutions can take decades, and so state and aid interventions also try to shape informal practices and norms governing disputes. Their goal is to improve bargaining and commitment, thus limiting disputes and violence. Mass education campaigns that promote alternative dispute resolution (ADR) are common examples of these interventions. We studied the short-term impacts of one such campaign in Liberia, where property disputes are endemic. Residents of 86 of 246 towns randomly received training in ADR practices and norms; this training reached 15% of adults. One year later, treated towns had higher resolution of land disputes and lower violence. Impacts spilled over to untrained residents. We also saw unintended consequences: more extrajudicial punishment and (weakly) more nonviolent disagreements. Results imply that mass education can change high-stakes behaviors, and improving informal bargaining and enforcement behavior can promote order in weak states.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 2014 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Amnesty International. 2009. Liberia. New York: Amnesty International.Google Scholar
Bardhan, Pranab. 1993. “Analytics of the Institutions of Informal Cooperation in Rural Development.” World Development 21: 633–9.Google Scholar
Bazerman, Max H., Curhan, Jared R., Moore, Don A., and Valley, Kathleen L.. 2000. “Negotiation.” Annual Review of Psychology 51: 279314.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Besley, Timothy, and Ghatak, Maitreesh. 2009. “Property Rights and Economic Development.” In Handbook of Development Economics, eds. Rodrik, Dani and Rosenzweig, Mark R.. New York: Elsevier, 4525–95.Google Scholar
Cloward, Karisa Tritz. 2010. “When Norms Collide: Micro-level Responses to the Transnational Campaign against Gender-Based Violence.” Ph.D diss., Yale University.Google Scholar
Collier, Paul, and Vicente, Pedro C.. 2011. “Votes and Violence: Evidence from a Field Experiment in Nigeria.” Unpublished working paper.Google Scholar
Deutsch, Morton, Coleman, Peter T., and Marcus, Eric C., eds. 2006. The Handbook of Conflict Resolution: Theory and Practice. 2nd ed. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass.Google Scholar
Edwards, H. T. 1986. “Alternative Dispute Resolution: Panacea or Anathema?Harvard Law Review 99: 668–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ellickson, Robert. 1991. Order without Law: How Neighbors Settle Disputes. Cambridge. MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Fearon, James D. 1998. “Bargaining, Enforcement, and International Cooperation.” International Organization 52 (2): 269305.Google Scholar
Finkel, Steven E., Horowitz, Jeremy, and Rojo-Mendoza, Reynaldo T.. 2012. “Civic Education and Democratic Backsliding in the Wake of Kenya's Post-2007 Election Violence.” Journal of Politics 74: 5265.Google Scholar
Finkel, Steven E., and Smith, Amy Erica. 2011. “Civic Education, Political Discussion and the Social Transmission of Democratic Knowledge and Values in a New Democracy: Kenya 2002.” American Journal of Political Science 55: 417–35.Google Scholar
Finnemore, Martha, and Sikkink, Kathryn. 1998. “International Norm Dynamics and Political Change.” International Organization 52: 887917.Google Scholar
Hartman, Alexandra. 2012. “Property Rights under Pressure: Conflict over Land in Liberia.” Unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, Yale University.Google Scholar
Isser, Deborah H., Lubkemann, Stephen C., and N'Tow, Saah. 2009. Looking for Justice: Liberian Experiences with and Perceptions of Local Justice Options. Washington, DC: U.S. Institute for Peace.Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel, and Tversky, Amos. 1995. “Conflict Resolution: A Cognitive Perspective.” In Barriers to Conflict Resolution, eds. Arrow, Kenneth J., Mnookin, Robert H., Ross, Lee, Tversky, Amos, and Wilson, Robert. New York: W. W. Norton, 4461.Google Scholar
Kennan, John, and Wilson, Robert. 1993. “Bargaining with Private Information.” Journal of Economic Literature 31 (1): 45104.Google Scholar
Knight, Jack. 1992. Institutions and Social Conflict. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lieberman, J. K., and Henry, J. F.. 1986. “Lessons from the Alternative Dispute Resolution Movement.” University of Chicago Law Review 53 (2): 424–39.Google Scholar
Mackie, Gerry. 1996. “Ending Footbinding and Infibulation: A Convention Account.” American Sociological Review 61 (6): 9991017.Google Scholar
Merry, Sally Engle. 1984. “Anthropology and the Study of Alternative Dispute Resolution.” Journal of Legal Education 34: 277.Google Scholar
Mnookin, Robert. 1998. “Alternative Dispute Resolution.” John M. Olin Center for Law, Economics and Business Discussion Paper 232. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Law School.Google Scholar
Moore, Sally Falk. 1973. “Law and Social Change: The Semi-autonomous Social Field as an Appropriate Subject of Study.” Law & Society Review 7 (1): 719–46.Google Scholar
North, Douglass C. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
North, Douglass C. 1994. “Institutions and Credible Commitment.” Working Paper in Economic History 9412002. St. Louis: Washington University.Google Scholar
Onoma, Ato Kwamena. 2010. The Politics of Property Rights Institutions in Africa. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Paluck, Elizabeth Levy, and Green, Donald P.. 2009. “Deference, Dissent, and Dispute Resolution: An Experimental Intervention Using Mass Media to Change Norms and Behavior in Rwanda.” American Political Science Review 103 (4): 622–44.Google Scholar
Pande, Rohini, and Udry, Christopher. 2005. “Institutions and Development: A View from Below.” In Proceedings of the 9th World Congress of the Econometric Society, eds. Blundell, Robert, Persson, Torsten, and Newey, W.. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Sternlight, Jean. 2006. “Is Alternative Dispute Resolution Consistent with the Rule of Law?DePaul Law Review 56: 569.Google Scholar
Unruh, Jon D. 2003. “Land Tenure and Legal Pluralism in the Peace Process.” Peace & Change 28 (3): 352–77.Google Scholar
Vinck, Patrick, Pham, Phuong, and Kreutzer, Tino. 2011. Talking Peace: A Population-based Survey on Attitudes about Security, Dispute Resolution, and Post-conflict Reconstruction in Liberia. Berkeley: UC Berkeley Human Rights Center.Google Scholar
Wantchekon, Leonard, and Vermeersch, Christel. 2011. “Information, Social Networks, and the Demand for Public Goods: Experimental Evidence from Benin.” In Accountability through Public Opinion: From Inertia to Public Action, eds. Odugbemi, Sina and Lee, Taeku. Washington, DC: World Bank Publications, 123–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar