Hostname: page-component-7c8c6479df-r7xzm Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-03-28T01:00:29.278Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Institutional change and information production

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  21 March 2013

FABIO LANDINI*
Affiliation:
MEDAlics and CRIOS, Bocconi University, Milan, Italy

Abstract:

The organization of information production is undergoing a deep transformation. Alongside corporations, which have been for long time the predominant institutions of information production, new organizational forms have emerged, e.g. free software communities, open-content on-line wikis, and collective blogs. The paper investigates the factors that favoured the emergence of these alternative systems, called peer production. Different from the previous literature, the paper considers technology as an endogenous variable in the process of organizational design. On this basis, the paper argues that the diffusion of digital technology is a necessary but not sufficient condition to explain the emergence of peer production. A similarly important role has been played by the set of ethics that motivated the early adherents to the free software movement. Such an ethics indeed operated as a ‘cultural subsidy’ that helped to overcome the complementarities existing among distinct institutional domains, and let a new organizational species to emerge.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Millennium Economics Ltd 2013 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Aoki, M. (2001), Toward a Comparative Institutional Analysis, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arrow, K. J. (1999), ‘Information and the Organization of Industry’, in Chirchilnisky, G. (ed.), Markets, Information, and Uncertainty: Essays in Economic Theory in Honor of Kenneth J. Arrow, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Baldwin, C. Y. and Clark, K. B. (2000), Design Rules, Vol. 1: The Power of Modularity, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baldwin, C. Y. and von Hippel, E. (2011), ‘Modelling a paradigm shift: From producer innovation to user and open collaborative innovation’, Organization Science, 22 (6): 13991417.Google Scholar
Benkler, Y. (2002a), ‘Coase's penguin, or Linux and the nature of the firm’, Yale Law Journal, 112 (3): 369446.Google Scholar
Benkler, Y. (2002b), ‘Intellectual property and the organization of information production’, International Review of Law and Economics, 22 (1): 81107.Google Scholar
Benkler, Y. (2006), The Wealth of Networks: How Social Production Transforms Markets and Freedom, New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Benkler, Y. and Nissenbaum, H. (2006), ‘Commons-based peer production and virtue’, Journal of Political Philosophy, 14 (4): 394419.Google Scholar
Berners-Lee, T. (1999), Weaving the Web: The Original Design and Ultimate Destiny of the World Wide Web, New York: HarperCollins Publishers Inc.Google Scholar
Bowles, S. (1985), ‘The production process in a competitive economy: Walrasian, neo-hobbesian, and marxian’, American Economic Review, 75 (1): 1636.Google Scholar
Braverman, H. (1974), Labour and Monopoly Capital: The Degradation of Work in the Twentieth Century, New York, NY: Monthly Review Press.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. (1937), ‘The nature of the firm’, Economica, 4 (16): 386405.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. (1960), ‘The problem of social costs’, Journal of Law and Economics, 3(October): 144.Google Scholar
David, P. D. and Rullani, F. (2008), ‘Dynamics of innovation in an open source collaboration environment: Lurking, laboring, and launching floss projects on Sourceforge’, Industrial and Corporate Change, 17 (4): 647710.Google Scholar
Earle, J., Pagano, U., and Lesi, M. (2006), ‘Information technology, organizational form, and transition to the market’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 60 (4): 471489.Google Scholar
Elkin-Loren, N. and Salzberger, E. M. (2000), ‘Law and economics in cyberspace’, International Review of Law and Economics, 19 (4): 553581.Google Scholar
Fristrup, J. A. (1994), Usenet: Netnews for Everyone, Upper Saddle River: Prentice Hall.Google Scholar
Hars, A. and Ou, S. (2002), ‘Working for free? Motivations for participating in open-source projects’, International Journal of Electronic Commerce, 6 (3): 2539.Google Scholar
Hart, O. D. (1995), Firms, Contracts and Financial Structure, Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Hertel, G., Nieder, S., and Herrmann, S. (2003), ‘Motivation of software developers in open source projects: An Internet-based survey of contributors to the Linux kernel’, Research Policy, 32 (7): 11591177.Google Scholar
Kauffman, S. (1993), The Origins of Order, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Landini, F. (2012), ‘Technology, property rights and organizational diversity in the software industry’, Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 23 (2): 137150.Google Scholar
Lessig, L. (2006), Code: version 2.0, New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Mac Cormack, A., Rusnak, J., and Baldwin, C. Y. (2006), ‘Exploring the structure of complex software designs: An empirical study of open source and proprietary code’, Management Science, 52 (7): 10151030.Google Scholar
Marglin, S. A. (1974), ‘What do bosses do? The origins and functions of hierarchy in capitalist production’, Review of Radical Political Economy, 6 (2): 60112.Google Scholar
McGowan, D. (2001), ‘Legal implications of open-source software’, University of Illinois Legal Review, 2001 (1): 241304.Google Scholar
Milgrom, P. and Roberts, J. (1990), ‘Rationalizability, lerning and equilibrium in games with strategic complementarities’, Econometrica, 58 (6): 12551277.Google Scholar
Moody, G. (2001), Rebel Code: Inside Linux and the Open Source Revolution, New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Narduzzo, A. and Rossi, A. (2005), ‘The Role of Modularity in Free/Open Source Software Development’, in Koch, S. (ed.), Free/Open Software Development, Hershey, PA: Idea Group Publishing.Google Scholar
Nelson, R. R. (1991), ‘Why do firms differ, and how does it matter?’, Strategic Management Journal, Winter Special Issue (12): 61–74.Google Scholar
Nuvolari, A. (2005), ‘Open source software development: Some historical perspectives’, First Monday, 10 (10).Google Scholar
Pagano, U. (1993), ‘Organizational equilibria and institutional stability’, in Bowles, S., Gintis, H. and Gustafsson, B. (eds.), Markets and Democracy: Participation, Accountability and Efficiency, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Pagano, U. (2011), ‘Interlocking complementarities and institutional change’, Journal of Institutional Economics, 7 (3): 373392.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pagano, U. and Rossi, M. A. (2004), ‘Incomplete contracts, intellectual property and institutional complementarities’, European Journal of Law and Economics, 18 (1): 5567.Google Scholar
Pagano, U. and Rowthorn, R. (1994), ‘Ownership, technology and institutional stability’, Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, 5 (2): 221242.Google Scholar
Raymond, E. S. (1999), The Cathedral and the Bazaar, Sebastopol: O'Reilly and Associates, Inc.Google Scholar
Reagle, J. M. J. (2010), Good Faith Collaboration: The Culture of Wikipedia, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Reidenberg, J. R. (1998), ‘Lex informatica: The formulation of information policy rules through technologyTexas Law Review, 76 (3), 553593.Google Scholar
Stallman, R. M. (2002), Free Software, Free Society: Selected Essays of Richard M. Stallman, Boston: GNU Press.Google Scholar
Stone, B. (2004), Who Let the Blogs Out? A Hyperconnected Peek at the World of Weblogs, New York: St. Martin's Press.Google Scholar
von Hippel, E. (2005), Democratizing Innovation, London: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (1985), The Economic Institutions of Capitalism, New York: The Free Press.Google Scholar