Hostname: page-component-7c8c6479df-995ml Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-03-26T21:57:22.344Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Monetary Populism in Nineteenth-Century America: An Open Economy Interpretation

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  03 March 2009

Jeffry A. Frieden
Affiliation:
Department of Government, Harvard University, Cambridge, MA 02138.

Abstract

The battle over gold is typically explained as driven by proinflation debtors. However, going off gold would also have caused a depreciation, raising tradable prices relative to nontradables prices and helping producers of exportable primary products. An analysis of Congressional votes on monetary legislation indicates that higher constituency debt levels were not associated with opposition to gold, whereas mining and agricultural production were. This suggests that gold politics was at least as much about the impact of the exchange rate on relative prices as it was about inflation of the overall price level.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The Economic History Association 1997

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Aldrich, John, and Nelson, Forrest. Linear Probability, Logit, and Probit Models. Newbury Park: Sage, 1984.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alesina, Alberto. “Politics and Business Cycles in Industrial Democracies.” Economic Policy 8 (1989): 5798.Google Scholar
Barnhart, John. “Rainfall and the Populist Party in Nebraska.” American Political Science Review 19, no. 3 (1925): 527–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bawn, Kathleen. “Strategic Responses to Institutional Change: Parties, Committees, and Multiple Referral.” Public Choice, forthcoming.Google Scholar
Bordo, Michael and Kydland, Finn. “The Gold Standard As a Rule: An Essay in Exploration.” Explorations in Economic History 32, no. 4 (1995): 423–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bordo, Michael, and Rockoff, Hugh. “The Gold Standard as a “Good Housekeeping Seal of Approval’.” this JOURNAL 56, no. 3 (1996): 389428.Google Scholar
Bowman, John D.Economic Analysis of Midwestern Farm Land Values and Farm Land Income, 1860 to 1900.” Yale Economic Essays 5, no. 2 (1965): 317–52.Google Scholar
Bowman, John, and Keehn, Richard. “Agricultural Terms of Trade in Four Midwestern States, 1870–1900.” this JOURNAL 34 (1974): 592609.Google Scholar
Brady, Dorothy. “Price Deflators for Final Product Estimates.” In Output, Employment, and Productivity in the United States After 1800. Studies in Income and Wealth Volume 30, 91111. New York: Columbia University Press, 1966.Google Scholar
Calomiris, Charles. “Greenback Resumption and Silver Risk: the Economics and Politics of Monetary Regime Change in the United States, 1862–.” In Monetary Regimes in Transition, edited by Bordo, Michael and Capie, Forrest, 86132. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1994.Google Scholar
Destler, I. M., and Randall, Henning C.. Dollar Politics: Exchange Rate Policymaking in the United States. Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics, 1989.Google Scholar
Dombusch, Rudiger. “Currency Depreciation, Hoarding, and Relative Prices.” Journal of Political Economy 81, no.4 (1973): 893915.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dombusch, Rudiger. “Devaluation, Money, and Nontraded Goods.” American Economic Review 63, no. 1 (1973): 871–80.Google Scholar
Dombusch, Rudiger. “Expectations and Exchange Rate Dynamics.” Journal of Political Economy 84, no. 6 (1976): 1161–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Drake, Louis. “Reconstruction of a Bimetallic Price Level.” Explorations in Economic History 22, no. 2 (1985): 194219.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eichengreen, Barry. “Mortgage Interest Rates in the Populist Era.” American Economic Review 74 (12 1984):9951015.Google Scholar
Eichengreen, Barry. “The Endogeneity of Exchange Rate Regimes.” In Understanding Interdependence, edited by Peter, Kenen, 333. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1995.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elliott, E. A., ed. Proceedings of the First National Silver Convention, Held at St. Louis, November 26, 27 and 28, 1889. St. Louis: Buxton and Skinner, 1889.Google Scholar
Farmer, Hattie. “The Economic Background of Frontier Populism.” Mississippi Valley Historical Review 10, no. 4 (1924): 406–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frieden, Jeifry. “Invested Interests: The Politics of National Economic Policies in a World of Global Finance,” International Organization 45, no. 4 (1991): 425–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frieden, Jeifry. “The Dynamics of International Monetary Systems: International and Domestic Factors in the Rise, Reign, and Demise of the Classical Gold Standard.” In Coping with Complexity in the International System, edited by Robert, Jervis and Jack, Snyder, 137–62. Boulder, CO: Westview Press, 1993.Google Scholar
Frieden, Jeifry. “Exchange Rate Politics: Contemporary Lessons from American History.” Review of International Political Economy 1, no. 1 (1994): 81103.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frieden, Jeifry. “Economic Integration and the Politics of Monetary Policy in the United States.” In Internationalization and Domestic Politics, edited by Keohane, Robert and Milner, Helen, 108–36. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedman, Milton. “The Crime of 1873.” Journal of Political Economy 98, no. 6 (1990): 1159–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedman, Milton, and Anna, Jacobson Schwartz. A Monetary History of the United States, 1867–1960. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1963.Google Scholar
Galiman, Robert. “Commodity Output, 1839–1899.” In Trends in the American Economy in the Nineteenth Century Studies in Income and Wealth Volume 24, 1343. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1960.Google Scholar
Goodwyn, Lawrence. Democratic Promise: The Populist Moment in America. New York: Oxford University Press, 1976.Google Scholar
Grilli, Vittorio, Masciandaro, Donato, and Tabellini, Guido. “Political and Monetary Institutions and Public Financial Policies in the Industrial Countries.” Economic Policy 13 (1991): 342–92.Google Scholar
Harvey, William. Coin’s Financial School, edited by Hofstadter, Richard. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1963.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hicks, John. “The Political Career of Ignatius Donnelly.” Mississippi Valley Historical Review 8, no. 1–2 (1921): 80132.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hicks, John. The Populist Revolt. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press, 1931.Google Scholar
Hoffman, Charles. “The Depression of the Nineties.” this JOURNAL 16, no. 2 (1956): 137–64.Google Scholar
Rogers, Hollingsworth J.. The Whirligig of Politics: The Democracy of Cleveland and Bryan. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1963.Google Scholar
Krueger, Anne O.Exchange-Rate Determination. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1983.Google Scholar
Lee, Susan Previant, and Passell, Peter. A New Economic View of American History. New York: Norton, 1979.Google Scholar
Mayhew, Anne. “A Reappraisal of the Causes of Farm Protest in the United States, 1870–1900.” this JOURNAL 32, no. 2 (1972): 464–75.Google Scholar
McGuire, Robert. “Economic Causes of Late-Nineteenth Century Agrarian Unrest: New Evidence.” this JOURNAL 41, no. 4 (1981): 835–52.Google Scholar
McNall, Scott. The Road to Rebellion. Class Formation and Kansas Populism, 1865–1900. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1988.Google Scholar
Miller, Raymond. “The Background of Populism in Kansas.” Mississippi Valley Historical Review 11, no.4 (1925): 469–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Neal, Larry. “Integration of International Capital Markets: Quantitative Evidence from the Eighteenth to Twentieth Centuries.” this JOURNAL 45, no. 2 (1985): 219–26.Google Scholar
Nugent, Walter. “Some Parameters of Populism.” Agricultural History 40, no. 4 (1966): 255–70.Google Scholar
Lawrence, . “The Efficiency of the Dollar-Sterling Gold Standard, 1890–1908.” Journal of Political Economy 94, no. 3 (1986): 1038–73.Google Scholar
Oppers Stefan. “Was the Worldwide Shift to Gold Inevitable? An Analysis of the End of Bimetallism.” Unpublished Manuscript.Google Scholar
Ostler, Jeffrey. Prairie Populism: The Fate ofAgrarian Radicalism in Kansas, Nebraska, and Iowa, 1880–1892. Lawrence: University Press of Kansas, 1993.Google Scholar
Rockoff, Hugh. “The “Wizard of Oz’ as a Monetary Allegory.” Journal of Political Economy 98, no. 4 (1990): 739–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shaw, William. Value of Commodity Output Since 1869. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research 1947.Google Scholar
Snowden, Kenneth. “Mortgage Rates and American Capital Market Development in the Late Nineteenth Century.” this JOURNAL 47, no. 3 (1987): 671–91.Google Scholar
Snowden, Kenneth. “Mortgage Lending and American Urbanization, 1880–1890.” this JOURNAL 48, no. 2 (1988): 273–85.Google Scholar
Snowden, Kenneth. The Evolution of Interregional Mortgage Lending Channels, 1870–1940. Unpublished manuscript.Google Scholar
Stevans, C. M.Free Silver and the People. A Campaign Handbook Against the Gold- Hoarding Millionaires. New York: F. Tennyson Neely, 1896.Google Scholar
Stock, James. “Real Estate Mortgages, Foreclosures, and Midwestern Agrarian Unrest, 1865–1920.” this JOURNAL 44, no. 1 (1984): 89105.Google Scholar
Sundquist, James L.Dynamics of the Party System. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution, 1983.Google Scholar
Timberlake, Richard. “Repeal of Silver Monetization in the Late Nineteenth Century.” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 10, no. 1 (1978): 2745.Google Scholar
Unger, Irwin. The Greenback Era: A Social and Political History of American Finance. 1865–1879. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1964.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
U.S. Bureau of the Census. Report on the Population of the United States at the Eleventh Census: 1890. volume 2: Population, Part II, and volume 20: Real Estate Mortgages. Washington, DC: GPO, 1895.Google Scholar
Warren, George, and Pearson, Frank. Gold and Prices. New York: John Wiley and Sons, 1935.Google Scholar
Weinstein, Allen. Prelude to Populism: Origins of the Silver Issue, 1867–1878. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1970.Google Scholar
Williams, Jeffrey C.Economics and Politics: Voting Behavior in Kansas during the Populist Decade.” Explorations in Economic History 18, no. 3 (1981): 233–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yohe, William. “An Economic Appraisal of the Sub-Treasury Plan.” Appendix B to Lawrence Goodwyn. Democratic Promise. The Populist Moment in America. New York: Oxford University Press, 1976: 571–81.Google Scholar