Hostname: page-component-7c8c6479df-8mjnm Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-03-28T11:53:50.269Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Regime Change and Revolutionary Entrepreneurs

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  09 September 2010

ETHAN BUENO DE MESQUITA*
Affiliation:
University of Chicago
*
Ethan Bueno de Mesquita is Associate Professor, Harris School of Public Policy Studies, University of Chicago, 1155 East 60th Street, Suite 108, Chicago, IL 60637 (bdm@uchicago.edu).

Abstract

I study how a revolutionary vanguard might use violence to mobilize a mass public. The mechanism is informational—the vanguard uses violence to manipulate population member's beliefs about the level of antigovernment sentiment in society. The model has multiple equilibria, one equilibrium in which there may be revolution and another in which there is certain not to be. In the former, structural factors influence expected mobilization, whereas in the latter they do not. Hence, the model is consistent with structural factors influencing the likelihood of revolution in some societies but not others, offering a partial defense of structural accounts from common critiques. The model also challenges standard arguments about the role of revolutionary vanguards. The model is consistent with vanguard violence facilitating mobilization and even sparking spontaneous uprisings. However, it also predicts selection effects—an active vanguard emerges only in societies that are already coordinated on a participatory equilibrium. Hence, a correlation between vanguard activity and mass mobilization may not constitute evidence for the causal efficacy of vanguards—be it through creating focal points, providing selective incentives, or communicating information.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 2010

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Angeletos, George-Marios, Hellwig, Christian, and Pavan, Alessandro. 2006. “Signaling in a Global Game: Coordination and Policy Traps.” Journal of Political Economy 114 (3): 452–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Angeletos, George-Marios, Hellwig, Christian, and Pavan, Alessandro. 2007. “Dynamic Global Games of Regime Change: Learning, Multiplicity, and the Timing of Attacks.” Econometrica 75 (3): 711–56.Google Scholar
Baliga, Sandeep and Sjöström, Tomas. 2004. “Arms Races and Negotiations.” Review of Economic Studies 71: 351–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baliga, Sandeep, and Sjöström, Tomas. 2009. “The Strategy of Manipulating Conflict.” Northwestern University. Typescript.Google Scholar
Berman, Eli. 2009. Radical Religious and Violent: The New Economics of Terrorism. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berman, Eli, and Laitin, David D.. 2008. “Religion, Terrorism and Public Goods: Testing the Club Model.” Journal of Public Economics 92 (10–11): 1942–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berman, Eli, Shapiro, Jacob N., and Felter, Joseph H.. 2009. “Can Hearts and Minds Be Bought? The Economics of Counterinsurgency in Iraq.” NBER Working Paper 14606.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bueno de Mesquita, Ethan. 2005. “The Quality of Terror.” American Journal of Political Science 49 (3): 515–30.Google Scholar
Bueno de Mesquita, Ethan, and Dickson, Eric. 2007. “The Propaganda of the Deed: Terrorism, Counterterrorism, and Moblization.” American Journal of Political Science 51 (2): 364–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carlsson, Hans, and van Damme, Eric. 1993. “Global Games and Equilibrium Selection.” Econometrica 61 (5): 9891018.Google Scholar
Chwe, Michael. 1998. “Culture, Circles, and Commercials: Publicity, Common Knowledge, and Social Coordination.” Rationality and Society 10: 4775.Google Scholar
Chwe, Michael. 1999. “Structure and Strategy in Collective Action.” American Journal of Sociology 105: 128–56.Google Scholar
Chwe, Michael. 2000. “Communication and Coordination in Social Networks.” Review of Economic Studies 67: 116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chwe, Michael. 2001. Rational Ritual: Culture, Coordination, and Common Knowledge. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
DeGroot, Morris H. 1970. Optimal Statistical Decisions. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
DeNardo, James. 1985. Power in Numbers: The Political Strategy of Protest and Rebellion. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Dewan, Torun, and Myatt, David P.. 2007. “Leading the Party: Coordination, Direction and Communication.” American Political Science Review 101 (4): 825–43.Google Scholar
Dewan, Torun, and Myatt, David P.. 2008. “The Qualities of Leadership: Direction, Communication, and Obfuscation.” American Political Science Review 102 (3): 351–68.Google Scholar
Dube, Oeindrila, and Vargas, Juan. 2009. “Commondity Price Shocks and Civil Conflict: Evidence from Colombia.” Universidad del Rosario. Typescript.Google Scholar
Echenique, Federico, and Edlin, Aaron. 2004. “Mixed Equilibria Are Unstable in Games of Strategic Complements.” Journal of Economic Theory 118 (1): 6179.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Edmond, Chris. 2007. “Information Manipulation, Coordination and Regime Change.” New York University. Typescript.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Edmond, Chris. 2008. “Information Revolutions and the Overthrow of Autocratic Regimes.” New York University. Typescript.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Finkel, Steven E., Muller, Edward N., and Opp, Karl-Dieter. 1989. “Personal Influence, Collective Rationality, and Mass Political Action.” American Political Science Review 83 (3): 885903.Google Scholar
Geddes, Barbara. 1990. “How the Cases You Choose Affect the Answers You Get: Selection Bias in Comparative Politics.” Political Analysis 2 (1): 131–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gillespie, Richard. 1995. “Political Violence in Argentina: Guerrillas, Terrorists, and Carapintadas.” In Terrorism in Context, ed. Crenshaw, Martha. University Park: Pennsylvania State University Press, 211–48.Google Scholar
Ginkel, John, and Smith, Alastair. 1999. “So You Say You Want a Revolution: A Game Theoretic Explanation of Revolution in Repressive Regimes.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 43 (3): 291316.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldstone, Jack A. 2001. “Toward a Fourth Generation of Revolutionary Theory.” Annual Review of Political Science 4 (June): 139–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hardin, Russell. 1996. One for All: The Logic of Group Conflict. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Holmström, Bengt. 1999. “Managerial Incentive Problems: A Dynamic Perspective.” Review of Economic Studies 66 (1): 169–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kalyvas, Stathis N. 1999. “Wanton and Senseless? The Logic of Massacres in Algeria.” Rationality and Society 11 (3): 243–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuran, Timor. 1989. “Sparks and Prairie Fires: A Theory of Unanticipates Political Revolution.” Public Choice 61 (1): 4174.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuran, Timor. 1991. “Now out of Never: The Element of Surprise in the Eastern European Revolution of 1989.” World Politics 44: 748.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kurrild-Klitgaard, Peter. 1997. Rational Choice, Collective Action, and the Paradox of Rebellion. Copenhagen: Institute of Political Science, University of Copenhagen.Google Scholar
Lichbach, Mark Irving. 1987. “Deterrence of Escalation?: The Puzzle of Aggregate Studies of Repression and Dissent.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 31: 266–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lichbach, Mark Irving. 1995. The Rebel's Dilemma. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Lohmann, Susanne. 1994. “The Dynamics of information Cascades: The Monday Demonstrations in Leipzig, East German, 1989–1991.” World Politics 47 (1): 42101.Google Scholar
Migdal, Joel. 1974. Peasants, Politics, and Revolution. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Morris, Stephen, and Shin, Hyun Song. 1998. “Unique Equilibrium in a Model of Self-fulfilling Currency Attacks.” American Economic Review 88 (3): 587–97.Google Scholar
Morris, Stephen, and Shin, Hyun Song. 2000. “Rethinking Multiple Equilibria in Macroeconomic Modeling.” NBER Macroeconomics Annual 15: 139–61.Google Scholar
Morris, Stephen, and Shin, Hyun Song. 2003. “Global Games: Theory and Applications.” In Advances in Economics and Econometrics: Theory and Applications, 8th World Congress of the Econometric Society, eds. Dewatripont, Mathias, Hansen, Lars Peter, and Turnovsky, Stephen J.. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Morris, Stephen, and Shin, Hyun Song. 2004. “Coordination Risk and the Price of Debt.” European Economic Review 48: 133–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olson, Mancur Jr., 1965. The Logic of Collective Action. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Opp, Karl-Dieter, Voss, Peter, and Gern, Christiane. 1995. Origins of Spontaneous Revolution: East Germany, 1989. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Popkin, Samuel L. 1979. The Rational Peasant: The Political Economy of Rural Society in Vietnam. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Popkin, Samuel L. 1988. “Political Entrepreneurs and Peasant Movements in Vietnam.” In Revolution and Rationality, ed. Taylor, Michael. Cambride: Cambridge University Press, 962.Google Scholar
Rosendorff, Peter and Sandler, Todd. 2004. “Too Much of a Good Thing? The Proactive Response Dilemma.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 48 (4): 657–71.Google Scholar
Schelling, Thomas C. 1960. The Strategy of Conflict. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Selbin, Eric. 1993. Modern Latin American Revolutions. Boulder, CO: Westview.Google Scholar
Siqueira, Kevin, and Sandler, Todd. 2007. “Terrorist Backlash, Terrorism Mitigation, and Policy Delegation.” Journal of Public Economics 91 (9): 1800–15.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skocpol, Theda. 1979. States and Social Revolutions: A Comparative Analysis of France, Russia, and China. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Tilly, Charles. 1975. “Revolutions and Collective Violence.” In Handbook of Political Science, Vol. 3: Macropolitical Theory, eds. Greenstein, Fred I. and Polsby, Nelson W.. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.Google Scholar
Tullock, Gordon. 1971. “The Paradox of Revolution.” Public Choice 11 (Fall): 89100.Google Scholar
Tullock, Gordon. 1974. The Social Dilemma: The Economics of War and Revolution. Blacksburg, VA: Center for the Study of Public Choice.Google Scholar
Wickham-Crowley, Timothy P. 1992. Guerrillas and Revolution in Latin America. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar