Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-qsmjn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-20T03:44:47.980Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Phoenix Risen: The Resurrection of Global Finance

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  13 June 2011

Benjamin J. Cohen
Affiliation:
University of California
Get access

Abstract

Of all the many changes of the world economy since World War II, few have been nearly so dramatic as the resurrection of global finance. A review of five recent books suggests considerable diversity of opinion concerning both the causes and the consequences of financial globalization, leaving much room for further research. Competing historical interpretations, stressing the contrasting roles of market forces and government policies, need to be reexamined for dynamic linkages among the variables they identify. Likewise, impacts on state policy at both the macro and micro levels should be explored more systematically to understand not just whether constraints may be imposed on governments but also how and under what conditions, and what policymakers can do about them. Finally, questions are also raised about implications for the underlying paradigm conventionally used for the study of international political economy and international relations more generally.

Type
Review Article
Copyright
Copyright © Trustees of Princeton University 1996

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 See, e.g., Wachtel, Howard M., The Money Mandarins: The Making of a New Supranational Economic Order (Armonk, N.Y.: M. E. Sharpe, 1990)Google Scholar; McKenzie, Richard B. and Lee, Dwight R., Quicksilver Capital: How the Rapid Movement of Wealth Has Changed the World (New York: Free Press, 1991)Google Scholar; Kurtzman, Joel, The Death of Money: How the Electronic Economy Has Destabilized the World's Markets and Created Financial Chaos (New York: Simon and Schuster, 1993)Google Scholar; Millman, Gregory J., The Vandals’ Crown: How Rebel Currency Traders Overthrew the World's Central Banks (New York: Free Press, 1995)Google Scholar; and Solomon, Steven, The Confidence Game: How Unelected Central Bankers Are Governing the Changed Global Economy (New York: Simon and Schuster, 1995)Google Scholar.

2 Strange, Susan, Casino Capitalism (New York: Basil Blackwell, 1986)Google Scholar.

3 Other recent contributions of note include Gill, Stephen R. and Law, David, “Global Hegemony and the Structural Power of Capital,” International Studies Quarterly 33 (December 1989)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Underhill, Geoffrey R. D., “Markets beyond Politics? The State and the Intemationalisation of Financial Markets,” European Journal of Political Research 19 (March-April 1991)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Banuri, Tariq and Schor, Juliet B., eds., Financial Openness and National Autonomy: Opportunities and Constraints (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1992)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Goodman, John B. and Pauly, Louis W., “The Obsolescence of Capital Controls? Economic Management in an Age of Global Markets,” World Politics 46 (October 1993)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Cerny, Philip G., ed., Finance and World Politics (Aldershot, England: Edward Elgar, 1993)Google Scholar; Andrews, David M., “Capital Mobility and State Autonomy: Toward a Structural Theory of International Monetary Relations,” International Studies Quarterly 38 (June 1994)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Corbridge, Stuart, Thrift, Nigel, and Martin, Ron, eds., Money, Power and Space (Cambridge: Basil Blackwell, 1994)Google Scholar; and Eric Helleiner, ed., “The World of Money: The Political Economy of International Capital Mobility,” Policy Sciences 27, no. 4 (1994)Google Scholar.

4 Frieden, Jeffry A., “Invested Interests: The Politics of National Economic Policies in a World of Global Finance,” International Organization 45 (Autumn 1991), 429CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

5 See, e.g., Frankel, Jeffrey A., On Exchange Rates (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1993)Google Scholar, chap. 2; Bosworth, Barry P., Saving and Investment in a Global Economy (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1993)Google Scholar, chap. 1; Shepherd, William F., International Financial Integration: History, Theory and Applications in OECD Countries (Brookfield, Vt.: Ashgate Publishing, 1994)Google Scholar, chap. 4; Herring, Richard J. and Litan, Robert E., Financial Regulation in the Global Economy (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1995)Google Scholar, chap. 2; and Ghosh, Atish R., “International Capital Mobility amongst the Major Industrialised Countries: Too Little or Too Much?” Economic Journal 105 (January 1995)CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Country (or political) risk refers to the possibility that assets may be treated differently by different sovereign governments; currency (or foreign-exchange) risk, to the possibility of exchange-rate movements that may alter the rate of return on investments. For some useful discussion, see Herring, Richard J., ed., Managing International Risk (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1983)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

6 Though unacknowledged by Sobel, use of the terms “outside-in” and “inside-out” to describe alternative approaches to the study of international relations was pioneered by Waltz, Kenneth. Waltz, See, Theory of World Politics (Reading, Mass.: Addison-Wesley, 1979), 63Google Scholar.

7 For parallel arguments concerning the critical role of domestic politics in shaping distinctive national patterns of financial liberalization, see Pauly, Louis W., Opening Financial Markets: Banking Politics on the Pacific Rim (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1988)Google Scholar; Rosenbluth, Frances McCall, Financial Politics in Contemporary Japan (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1989)Google Scholar; and Maxfield, Sylvia, Governing Capital: International Finance and Mexican Politics (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1990)Google Scholar.

8 Philip G. Cerny, “The Deregulation and Re-regulation of Financial Markets in a More Open World,” in Cerny (fn. 3), chap. 3.

9 Each of these levels of analysis has its analogue in one of Kenneth Waltz's three “images” of international relations—respectively, the third, second, and first image. Waltz, See, Man, the State and War (New York: Columbia University Press, 1959)Google Scholar.

10 Bryant, Ralph C., International Financial Intermediation (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1987), 69Google Scholar.

11 Andrews (fn. 3). See also Cerny, Philip G., “The Dynamics of Financial Globalization: Technology, Market Structure, and Policy Response,” Policy Sciences 27, no. 4 (1994)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

12 Eric Helleiner, “Post-Globalization: Is the Financial Liberalization Trend Irreversible?” in Daniel Drache and R. Boyer, eds., The Future of Nations and the Limits of Markets (forthcoming).

13 Andrews (fn. 3), 197. See also idem, “Capital Mobility and Monetary Adjustment in Western Europe, 1973–1991,” Policy Sciences 27, no. 4 (1994)Google Scholar; Philip G. Cerny, “The Political Economy of International Finance,” in Cerny (fn. 3), chap. 1; and idem (fn. 11).

14 Pauly, Louis W., “Capital Mobility, State Autonomy and Political Legitimacy,” Journal of InternationalAffairs 48 (Winter 1995), 373, 385Google Scholar. Andrews himself (fn. 3) admits that “this is not to say that the current degree of capital mobility cannot be reduced, but instead that reduction is likely to be both difficult and costly” (p. 198).

15 James, Scott C. and Lake, David A., “The Second Face of Hegemony: Britain's Repeal of the Corn Laws and the American Walker Tariff of 1846,” International Organization 43 (Winter 1989)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

16 Uniquely, Japan was the object of considerable and quite direct pressure from the United States to liberalize its financial markets, particularly during the 1980s. For detail, see Rosenbluth (fn. 7), chap. 3. Overt exercise of influence by the U.S. as well as Britain has been much more evident in the negotiation of regulatory responses to financial globalization, as Kapstein emphasizes (chap. 5).

17 Ron Martin, “Stateless Monies, Global Financial Integration and National Economic Autonomy: The End of Geography?” in Corbridge, Thrift, and Martin (fn. 3), 271.

18 Cerny (fn. 8), 51. Andrews (fn. 3), similarly speaks of the critical role of “widely shared ideological commitments” and “mindsets” (pp. 200–201).

19 Gill and Law (fn. 3), 483–84.

20 Cerny (fn. 8), 79.

21 Goodman and Pauly (fn. 3), 79. Andrews (fn. 3) criticizes Goodman and Pauly for this suggestion, charging that, by stressing both market forces and preexisting levels of financial integration, they in effect “treat capital mobility as both an independent and dependent variable” (p. 197). In fact, this is a bit unfair, since Goodman and Pauly clearly have in mind a kind of dynamic sequencing model or step-function in which today's dependent variable is tomorrow's independent variable (and vice versa).

22 Goodman and Pauly (fn. 3), 79.

23 McKenzie and Lee (fn. 1), xi.

24 Millman (fn. 1), 24.

25 Cohen, Benjamin J., “The Triad and the Unholy Trinity: Lessons for the Pacific Region,” in Higgott, Richard, Leaver, Richard, and Ravenhill, John, eds., Pacific Economic Relations in the 1990s: Cooperation or Conflict? (Boulder, Colo.: Lynne Reinner, 1993)Google Scholar. Adding free trade to the equation produces what Tommaso Padoa-Sehioppa calls the “inconsistent quartet.” See Padoa-Schioppa, “The European Monetary System: A Long-term View,” in Giavazzi, Francesco, Micossi, Stefano, and Miller, Marcus, eds., The European Monetary System (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1988)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

26 Cohen (fn. 25), 147.

27 See esp. Webb, Michael C., “International Economic Structures, Government Interests, and International Coordination of Macroeconomic Adjustment Policies,” International Organization 45 (Summer 1991)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Goodman and Pauly (fn. 3); Cohen (fn. 25); Andrews (fn. 3).

28 Andrews (fn. 3).

29 Ibid., 203.

30 Thomas A. Friedman, “Don't Mess with Moody's,” New York Times, February 22, 1995, p. A15. For a more general analysis of the role that credit-rating agencies may play in constraining public policy, see Sinclair, Timothy J., “Between State and Market: Hegemony and Institutions of Collective Action under Conditions of International Capital Mobility,” Policy Sciences 27, no. 4 (1994)CrossRefGoogle Scholar. For more specific detail on the Mexican experience, see Nairn, Moises, “Mexico's Larger Story,” Foreign Policy 99 (Summer 1995)Google Scholar.

31 Maxfield, Sylvia, “International Portfolio Flows to Developing/Transitional Economies: Impact on Government Policy Choice” (Manuscript, Yale University, 1995)Google Scholar.

32 Eichengreen, Barry, International Monetary Arrangements for the 21st Century (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1994), 56Google Scholar.

33 Ibid., 60.

34 Henning, C. Randall, Currencies and Politics in the United States, Germany, andjapan (Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Economics, 1994)Google Scholar.

35 Goodman and Pauly (fn. 3), 51.

36 Andrews (fn. 3), 206–7.

37 For recent surveys of OCA theory, see Masson, Paul R. and Taylor, Mark P., “Currency Unions: A Survey of the Issues,” in Masson, and Taylor, , eds., Policy Issues in the Operation of Currency Unions (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1993)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Tavlas, George S., “The ‘New'theory of Optimum Currency Areas,” World Economy 16 (November 1993)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

38 Frieden (fn. 4), 433.

40 Hirschman, Albert O., Exit, Voice and Loyalty: Responses to Decline in Firms, Organizations, and States (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1970)Google Scholar.

41 Gill and Law (fn. 3), 486–88.

42 See, e.g., Thomas I. Palley, “Capital Mobility and the Threat to American Prosperity,” Challenge (November-December 1994).

43 Bates, Robert H. and Lien, Da-Hsiang Donald, “A Note on Taxation, Development, and Representative Government,” Politics and Society 14 (March 1985), 57CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Bates and Lien note that their argument leads them to precisely the opposite conclusion from Hirschman, who reasoned that it was owners of immobile resources who would be more likely to take the political initiative. Hirschman's error, they suggest, was to focus on the motivations of private groups alone without regard to their strategic interaction with government. Political authorities anxious to preserve their tax base will always pay more attention to the owners of mobile resources. Ibid., 61.

44 Moses, Jonathan W., “Abdication from National Policy Autonomy: What's Left to Leave?” Politics and Society 12 (June 1994), 140–42Google Scholar.

45 Steinmo, Sven, “The End of Redistribution? International Pressures and Domestic Tax Policy Choices,” Challenge (November-December 1994), 17Google Scholar.

46 Thus Ton Notermans criticizes Jonathan Moses for his preoccupation with capital mobility in explaining the Swedish and Norwegian experiences, to the exclusion of what Notermans regards as even more important domestic factors. Notermans, , “Social Democracy in Open Economies: A Reply to Jonathan Moses,” Politics and Society 22 (June 1994)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

47 Garrett, Geoffrey and Lange, Peter, “Political Responses to Interdependence: What's ‘Left’ for the Left?” International Organization 45 (Autumn 1991)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

48 Ibid., 541.

49 Pauly, Louis W., “National Financial Structures, Capital Mobility, and International Economic Rules: The Normative Consequences of East Asian, European, and American Distinctiveness,” Policy Sciences 27, no. 4 (1994)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

50 Frieden (fn. 4), 430.

51 Milner, Helen V., “Bargaining and Cooperation: Domestic Games and International Relations” (Manuscript, Columbia University, 1995)Google Scholar.

52 Pauly (fn. 14), 373.

53 Cohen (fn. 25), 134.

54 Goodman and Pauly (fn. 3), 52.

55 Grieco, Joseph M., “Anarchy and the Limits of Cooperation: A Realist Critique of the Newest Liberal Institutionalism,” International Organization 42 (August 1988)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

56 Cerny (fn. 8); and idem, “The Infrastructure of the Infrastructure? Toward ‘Embedded Financial Orthodoxy’ in the International Political Economy,” in Palen, Ronen P. and Gills, Barry, eds., Transcending the State-Global Divide: A Neostructuralist Agenda in International Relations (Boulder, Colo.: Lynne Rienner, 1994)Google Scholar.

57 For a useful recent survey, see Rittberger, Volker, ed., Regime Theory and International Relations (New York: Oxford University Press, 1993)Google Scholar.

58 Stein, Arthur A., Why Nations Cooperate: Circumstance and Choice in International Relations (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1990)Google Scholar, chap. 2.

59 Kenen, Peter B., Managing Exchange Rates (New York: Council on Foreign Relations, 1988), 7577Google Scholar.

60 Herring and Litan (fn. 5), chap. 5.

61 For evidence of developing cooperation in the regulation of securities markets, see Porter, Tony, States, Markets and Regimes in Global Finance (New York: St. Martin's Press, 1993)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Coleman, William D. and Porter, Tony, “Regulating International Banking and Securities: Emerging Co-operation among National Authorities,” in Stubbs, Richard and Underhill, Geoffrey R. D., eds., Political Economy and the Changing Global Order (New York: St. Martin's Press, 1994)Google Scholar. For some observers, regulatory convergence amounts to a “re-regulation” of financial markets. See Underhill (fn. 3), Cerny (fn. 8).

62 Cohen (fn. 25); Kenen (fn. 59).

63 Webb(fn.27).

64 O'Brien, Richard, Global Financial Integration: The End of Geography (New York: Council on Foreign Relations, 1992), 5Google Scholar. See also Ohmae, Kenichi, The Borderless World: Power and Strategy in an Interdependent Economy (New York: Harper Business, 1990)Google Scholar; Martin (fn. 17).

65 O'Brien (fn. 64), 2.

66 Ibid., 76.

67 Paul Krugman, Geography andTrade (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1991), 25.

68 Kindleberger, Charles P., American Business Abroad (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1969), 207Google Scholar.

69 Cecco, Marcello De, “Financial Relations: Between Internationalism and Transnationalism,” in Morgan, Roger et al., eds., New Diplomacy in the Post-Cold War World: Essays for Susan Strange (New York: St. Martin's, 1993)Google Scholar.

70 Cerny, Philip G., “Money and Finance in the International Political Economy: Structural Change and Paradigmatic Muddle,” Review of International Political Economy 1 (Autumn 1994), 591Google Scholar.

71 Ruggie, John Gerard, “Territoriality and Beyond: Problematizing Modernity in International Relations,” International Organization 47 (Winter 1993)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Krasner, Stephen D., “Westphalia and All That,” in Goldstein, Judith D. and Keohane, Robert O., eds., Ideas and Foreign Policy: Beliefs, Institutions, and Political Change (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1993)Google Scholar; and Thomson, Janice E., “State Sovereignty in International Relations: Bridging the Gap between Theory and Empirical Research,” International Studies Quarterly 39 (June 1995)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

72 Agnew, John A., “The Territorial Trap: The Geographical Assumptions of International Relations Theory,” Review of International Political Economy 1 (Spring 1994)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

73 Agnew, John A., “Timeless Space and State-Centrism: The Geographical Assumptions of International Relations Theory,” in Rosow, Stephen J., Inayatullah, Naeem, and Rupert, Mark, eds., The Global Economy as Political Space (Boulder, Colo.: Lynne Reinner, 1994), 89Google Scholar.

74 Rosow, Stephen J., “On the Political Theory of Political Economy: Conceptual Ambiguity and the Global Economy,” Review of International Political Economy 1 (Autumn 1994), 473–75CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

75 Ruggie (fn. 71), 172.