Hostname: page-component-7c8c6479df-5xszh Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-03-18T18:41:23.526Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Law of k/n: The Effect of Chamber Size on Government Spending in Bicameral Legislatures

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  08 November 2007

JOWEI CHEN
Affiliation:
Stanford University
NEIL MALHOTRA
Affiliation:
Stanford University

Abstract

Recent work in political economics has examined the positive relationship between legislative size and spending, which Weingast et al. (1981) formalized as the law of 1/n. However, empirical tests of this theory have produced a pattern of divergent findings. The positive relationship between seats and spending appears to hold consistently for unicameral legislatures and for upper chambers in bicameral legislatures but not for lower chambers. We bridge this gap between theory and empirics by extending Weingast et al.'s model to account for bicameralism in the context of a Baron–Ferejohn bargaining game. Our comparative statics predict, and empirical data from U.S. state legislatures corroborate, that the size of the upper chamber (n) is a positive predictor of expenditure, whereas the ratio of lower-to-upper chamber seats (k) exhibits a negative effect. We refer to these relationships as the law of k/n, as the two variables influence spending in opposite directions.

Type
ARTICLES
Copyright
© 2007 by the American Political Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Ansolabehere Stephen, James M. Snyder, and Michael M. Ting. 2003. “Bargaining in Bicameral Legislatures: When and Why Does Malapportionment Matter?American Political Science Review 97 (August): 471481.Google Scholar
Banks Jeffrey S., and John Duggan. 2000. “A Bargaining Model of Collective Choice.” American Political Science Review 94 (March): 7388.Google Scholar
Baqir Reza. 2002. “Districting and Government Overspending.” Journal of Political Economy 110 (December): 13181354.Google Scholar
Baron David P., and John A. Ferejohn. 1989. “Bargaining in Legislatures.” American Political Science Review 83 (December): 11811206.Google Scholar
Beck Nathaniel, and Jonathan N. Katz. 1995. “What To Do (and Not To Do) with Time-Series Cross-Section Data.” American Political Science Review 89 (September): 634647.Google Scholar
Bradbury John C., and William M. Crain. 2001. “Legislative Organization and Government Spending: Cross-Country Evidence.” Journal of Public Economics 82 (December): 309325.Google Scholar
Bradbury John C., and E. Frank Stephenson. 2003. “Local Government Structure and Public Expenditures.” Public Choice 115 (April): 185198.Google Scholar
Breusch Trevor S., and Adrian R. Pagan. 1979. “A Simple Test for Heteroskedasticity and Random Coefficient Variation.” Econometrica 47 (September): 12871294.Google Scholar
Buchanan James M., and Gordon Tullock. 1962. The Calculus of Consent: Logical Foundations of Constitutional Democracy. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.
Bureau of Economic Analysis. Various years. “Gross Domestic Product (GDP) by State.” Washington, D.C.: USGPO.
Council of State Governments. Various years. The Book of the States. Lexington, KY: Council of State Governments.
Cox Gary. 2006. “The Organization of Democratic Legislatures.” In The Oxford Handbook of Political Economy, ed. Barry R. Weingast and Donald A. Wittman. Oxford; UK: Oxford University Press.
Gilligan Thomas W., and John G. Matsusaka. 1995. “Deviations from Constituent Interests: The Role of Legislative Structure and Political Parties in the States.” Economic Inquiry 33 (July): 383401.Google Scholar
Gilligan Thomas W., and John G. Matsusaka. 2001. “Fiscal Policy, Legislature Size, and Political Parties: Evidence from the First Half of the Twentieth Century.” National Tax Journal 54 (March): 5782.Google Scholar
Gilligan Thomas W., and John G. Matsusaka. 2006. “Public Choice Principles of Redistricting.” Public Choice 129 (December): 381398.Google Scholar
Hardy LeRoy C., Alan Heslop, and Stuart Anderson, eds. 1981. Reapportionment Politics: The History of Redistricting in the 50 States. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage.
Huber John D., and Nolan McCarty. 2004. “Bureaucratic Capacity, Delegation, and Political Reform.” American Political Science Review 98 (August): 481494.Google Scholar
Huber John D., and Charles R. Shipan. 2002. Deliberate Discretion? The Institutional Foundations of Bureaucratic Autonomy. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
Malhotra Neil. 2006. “Government Growth and Professionalism in U.S. State Legislatures.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 31 (November): 563584.Google Scholar
Niemi Richard G., Jeffrey S. Hill, and Bernard Grofman. 1985. “The Impact of Multimember Districts on Party Representation in U.S. State Legislatures.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 10 (November): 441455.Google Scholar
Owings Stephanie, and Rainald Borck. 2000. “Legislative Professionalism and Government Spending: Do Citizen Legislators Really Spend Less?Public Finance Review 28 (May): 210225.Google Scholar
Persson Torsten, and Guido Tabellini. 2003. The Economic Effects of Constitutions. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Primo David M. 2006. “Stop Us Before We Spend Again: Institutional Constraints on Government Spending.” Economics & Politics. 18 (November): 269297.Google Scholar
Primo David M., and James M. Snyder Jr., 2005. “Public Goods and the Law of 1/n.” Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association, Chicago, IL.
Shepsle Kenneth A., and Barry R. Weingast. 1981. “Political Preferences for the Pork Barrel: A Generalization.” American Journal of Political Science 26 (February): 96111.Google Scholar
Squire Peverill. 1988. “Career Opportunities and Membership Stability in Legislatures.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 13 (February): 6582.Google Scholar
Tsebelis George. 2002. Veto Players: How Political Institutions Work. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
U.S. Census Bureau. Various years. Government Finances. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office.
U.S. Census Bureau. Various years. Statistical Abstract of the United States. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office.
Weingast Barry R. 1994. “Reflections on Distributive Politics and Universalism.” Political Research Quarterly 47 (June): 319327.Google Scholar
Weingast Barry R., Kenneth A. Shepsle, and Christopher Johnsen. 1981. “The Political Economy of Benefits and Costs: A Neoclassical Approach to Distributive Politics.” Journal of Political Economy 89 (August): 64264.Google Scholar
Wooldridge Jeffrey M. 2002. Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.