Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-qsmjn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-25T04:56:25.078Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Can More Be Less? An Experimental Test of the Resource Curse

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  20 August 2014

Omar Al-Ubaydli
Affiliation:
Senior Fellow, Bahrain Center for Strategic, International and Energy Studies, PO Box 496, Manama, Bahrain; Affiliated Associate Professor of Economics, George Mason University, Fairfax, VA, USA; Affiliated Senior Research Fellow, Mercatus Center, George Mason University, Fairfax, VA, USA; e-mail: omar@omar.ec
Kevin McCabe
Affiliation:
Professor of Economics, George Mason University, Fairfax, VA, USA; e-mail: kmccabe@gmu.edu
Peter Twieg
Affiliation:
Graduate Student, Department of Economics, George Mason University, Fairfax, VA, USA; e-mail: ptwieg@gmu.edu

Abstract

Several scholars have argued that abundant natural resources can be harmful to economic performance under bad institutions and helpful when institutions are good. These arguments have either been theoretical or based on naturally occurring variation in natural resource wealth. We test this theory by using a laboratory experiment to reap the benefits of randomized control. We conduct this experiment in a virtual world (Second Life™) to make institutions more visceral. We find support for the theory.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The Experimental Research Section of the American Political Science Association 2014 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S. and Robinson, J. 2001. The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation. American Economic Review 91: 13691401.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D. and Robinson, J. 2006. Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D., Verdierand, T., Robinson, J. 2004. Kleptocracy and Divide-and-Rule: A Model of Personal Rule. Journal of the European Economic Association 2: 162–92.Google Scholar
Alexeev, M. and Conrad, R. 2009. The Elusive Curse of Oil. Review of Economics and Statistics 91: 586–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Al-Ubaydli, O. 2011. Natural Resources and the Tradeoff Between Authoritarianism and Development. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 81 (1): 137–52.Google Scholar
Andersen, S. and Aslaksen, J. 2008. Constitutions and the Resource Curse. Journal of Development Economics 87: 227–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Atlas, S. and Putterman, L. 2011. Trust Among the Avatars: A Virtual World Experiment, with and Without Textual and Visual Cues. Southern Economic Journal, Forthcoming.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Auty, R. 2001. Resource Abundance and Economic Development. Oxford World Institute for Development Economics Research, Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Banerjee, A. and Duflo, E. 2009. The Experimental Approach to Development Economics. Annual Review of Economics 1: 151–78.Google Scholar
Bateson, M., Nettle, D. and Roberts, G. 2006. Cues of Being Watched Enhance Cooperation in a Real-World Setting. Biology Letters 2: 412–14.Google Scholar
Baye, M., Kovenock, D. and De Vries, C. 1994. The Solution to the Tullock Rent-Seeking Game When R > 2: Mixed-Strategy Equilibria and Mean Dissipation Rates. Public Choice 81: 363–80.Google Scholar
Bente, G., Rüggenberg, S., Krämer, N., and Eschenburg, F. 2008. Avatar-Mediated Networking: Increasing Social Presence and Interpersonal Trust in Net-Based Collaborations. Human Communication Research 34: 287318.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blume, A. and Ortmann, A. 2007. The Effects of Costless Pre-Play Communication: Experimental Evidence from Games with Pareto-Ranked Equilibria. Journal of Economic Theory 132: 274–90.Google Scholar
Brandts, J. and Cooper, D. 2005. It's What You Say Not What You Play. Working Paper, Case Western University.Google Scholar
Bulte, E. and Damania, R. 2008. Resources for Sale: Corruption, Democracy and the Natural Resource Curse. The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis and Policy 8: article 5.Google Scholar
Burton, A. and Sefton, M. 2001. Risk, Pre-Play Communication and Equilibrium. Games and Economic Behavior 46: 2340.Google Scholar
Charness, G. and Gneezy, U. 2008. What's in a Name? Anonymity and Social Distance in Dictator and Ultimatum Games. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 68: 2935.Google Scholar
Charness, G. and Grosskopf, B. 2004. What Makes Cheap Talk Effective? Experimental Evidence. Economics Letters 83: 383–89.Google Scholar
Charness, G., Haruvy, E. and Sonsino, D. 2007. Social Distance and Reciprocity: An Internet Experiment. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 63: 88103.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chesney, T., Chuah, S. and Hoffmann, R. 2009. Virtual World Experimentation: An Exploratory Study. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 72: 618–35.Google Scholar
Compton, R., Giedeman, D. and Johnson, N. 2010. Investing in Institutions. Economics and Politics 22: 419–45.Google Scholar
Cooper, R., DeJong, D., Forsythe, R. and Ross, T. 1992. Communication in Coordination Games. Quarterly Journal of Economics 107: 739–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Duffy, J. and Feltovich, N. 2002. Do Actions Speak Louder Than Words? An Experimental Comparison of Observation and Cheap Talk. Games and Economic Behavior 39: 127.Google Scholar
Engerman, S. and Sokoloff, K. 1997. Factor Endowments, Institutions and Differential Paths of Growth Among New World Economies. In How Latin America Fell Behind, ed. Haber, S.. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 260306.Google Scholar
Fielder, M., Haruvy, E. and Li, S. 2011. Social Distance in a Virtual World Experiment. Games and Economic Behavior 72 (2): 400–26.Google Scholar
Fischbacher, U. 2007. z-Tree: Zurich Toolbox for Ready-Made Economic Experiments. Experimental Economics 10: 171–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frankel, J. 2010. The Natural Resource Curse: A Survey. NBER Working Paper 15863.Google Scholar
Greif, A. 2006. Institutions and the Path to the Modern Economy: Lessons from Medieval Trade. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hodler, R. 2006. The Curse of Natural Resources in Fractionalized Countries. European Economic Review 50: 1367–86.Google Scholar
Kang, S., Watt, J. and Ala, S. 2008. Communicators’ Perceptions of Social Presence as a Function of Avatar Realism in Small Display Mobile Communication Devices. In Proceedings of the 41st Hawaii International Conference on System Sciences. Washington, DC: IEEE Computer Society, 110.Google Scholar
Kimbrough, E., Smith, V. and Wilson, B. 2008. Historical Property Rights, Sociality, and the Emergence of Interpersonal Exchange in Long-Distance Trade. American Economic Review 98: 1009–39.Google Scholar
Knapp, G. and Murphy, J. 2010. Voluntary Approaches to Transitioning from Competitive Fisheries to Rights-Based Management: Bringing the Field Into the Lab. Agricultural and Resource Economics Review 39: 245–61.Google Scholar
Lakin, J., Jefferis, V., Cheng, C. and Chartrand, T. 2003. The Chameleon Effect as Social Glue: Evidence for the Evolutionary Significance of Nonconscious Mimicry. Journal of Nonverbal Behavior 27: 145–62.Google Scholar
Leibbrandt, A. and Lynham, J. 2013. Does the Resource Curse Exist? An Experimental Test. Working Paper, Monash University.Google Scholar
McCabe, K., Twieg, P. and Weel, J. 2011. Investigating the Endogenous Emergence of Social Networks and Trade: A Virtual Worlds Experiment. Working Paper, George Mason University.Google Scholar
Mehlum, H., Moene, K. and Torvik, R. 2006. Institutions and the Resource Curse. Economic Journal 116: 120.Google Scholar
Morgan, J. and Sefton, M. 2000. Funding Public Goods with Lotteries: Experimental Evidence. Review of Economic Studies 67: 785810.Google Scholar
North, D. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
North, D., Wallis, J. and Weingast, B. 2009. Violence and Social Orders: A Conceptual Framework for Interpreting Recorded Human History. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nowak, K., Watt, J., and Walther, J. 2005. The Influence of Synchrony and Sensory Modality on the Person Perception Process in Computer-Mediated Groups. Journal of Computer-Mediated Communication 10: article 3.Google Scholar
Nti, K. 1997. Comparative Statistics of Contests and Rent-Seeking Games. International Economic Review 38: 4359.Google Scholar
Olsson, O. 2006. Diamonds Are a Rebel's Best Friend. World Economy 29: 1133–50.Google Scholar
Olsson, O. 2007. Conflict Diamonds. Journal of Development Economics 82: 267–86.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E. 2000. Collective Action and the Evolution of Social Norms. Journal of Economic Perspectives 14: 137–58.Google Scholar
Potters, J., de Vries, C., and van Winden, F. 1998. An Experimental Examination of Rational Rent-Seeking. European Journal of Political Economy 14: 783800.Google Scholar
Robinson, J., Torvikand, R. and Verdier, T. 2005. Political Foundations of the Resource Curse. Journal of Development Economics 79: 447–68.Google Scholar
Ross, M. 2001. Does Oil Hinder Democracy? World Politics 53: 325–61.Google Scholar
Sachs, J. and Warner, A. 1995. Natural Resource Abundance and Economic Growth. NBER Working Paper 5398.Google Scholar
Torvik, R. 2002. Natural Resources, Rent-Seeking and Welfare. Journal of Development Economics 67: 455–70.Google Scholar
Tullock, G. 1980. Efficient Rent Seeking. In Toward a Theory of the Rent-Seeking Society, eds. Buchanan, J., Tollison, R., and Tullock, G.. College Station, TX: Texas A&M University Press, 97112.Google Scholar
Tsui, K. 2009. More Oil, Less Democracy? Theory and Evidence from Crude Oil Discoveries. Economic Journal, Forthcoming.Google Scholar
Vicente, P. 2010. Does Oil Corrupt? Evidence from a Natural Experiment in West Africa. Journal of Development Economics 92: 2838.Google Scholar
Walker, J., Gardner, R. and Ostrom, E. 1990. Rent Dissipation in a Limited-Access Common-Pool Resource: Experimental Evidence. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 19: 203–11.Google Scholar
Supplementary material: PDF

Al-Ubaydli Supplementary Material

Al-Ubaydli Supplementary Material

Download Al-Ubaydli Supplementary Material(PDF)
PDF 1.1 MB