Hostname: page-component-7c8c6479df-8mjnm Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-03-29T06:48:55.571Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Spatial Models of Delegation

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  21 June 2004

JONATHAN BENDOR
Affiliation:
Stanford University
ADAM MEIROWITZ
Affiliation:
Princeton University

Abstract

Although a large literature on delegation exists, few models have pushed beyond a core set of canonical assumptions. This approach may be justified on grounds of tractability, but the failure to grasp the significance of different assumptions and push beyond specific models has limited our understanding of the incentives for delegation. Consequently, the justifications for delegation that have received recent scrutiny and testing differ from some of the more plausible justifications offered by informal studies of delegation. We show that surprisingly few results in the literature hinge on risk aversion, and surprisingly many turn on the ignored, though equally canonical, technological assumption that uncertainty is fixed (relative to policies). Relaxing the key assumptions about dimensionality and functional forms provides a clearer intuition about delegation—one that is closer to classical treatments. The theory allows us to relate different institutional features (commitment, specialization costs, monitoring, multiple principals) to delegation's observable properties.

Type
ARTICLES
Copyright
© 2004 by the American Political Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Baron David P., and Adam Meirowitz. 2002. “Relations between Fully-Revealing Equilibria of Multiple-Sender Signaling and Screening Models.” Typescript. Princeton University.
Battaglini Marco. 2002. “Multiple Referrals and Multidimensional Cheap Talk.Econometrica. 70 (4): 13791401.Google Scholar
Bawn K. 1995. “Political Control Versus Expertise: Congressional Choices about Administrative Procedures.” American Political Science Review 89 (March): 6273.Google Scholar
Bendor Jonathan, Amihai Glazer, and Thomas H. Hammond. 2001. “Theories of Delegation.” Annual Review of Political Science 4: 23569.Google Scholar
Bendor Jonathan, and Adam Meirowitz. 2003a. “Spatial Models of Delegation.” Graduate School of Business Working Paper Series, Stanford University.
Bendor Jonathan, and Adam Meirowitz. 2003b. “Supplementary Appendix to Spatial Models of Delegation.” Typescript Princeton University.
Epstein David. 1997. “An Informational Rationale for Committee Gatekeeping Power.” Public Choice 91 (3–4): 27199.Google Scholar
Epstein David. 1998. “Partisan and Bipartisan Signaling in Congress.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 14 (October): 183204.Google Scholar
Epstein David. 1999. “Legislating from Both Sides of the Aisle: Information and the Value of Bipartisan Consensus.” Public Choice 101 (1–2): 122.Google Scholar
Epstein David, and Sharyn O'Halloran. 1999. Delegating Powers: A Transaction Cost Politics Approach to Policy Making under Separate Powers. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Ferejohn John. 1986. “Incumbent Performance and Electoral Control.” Public Choice 50 (1–3): 525.Google Scholar
Gilligan Thomas, and Keith Krehbiel. 1987. “Collective Decision-Making and Standing Committees: An Informational Rationale for Restrictive Amendment Procedures.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 3 (Fall): 287335.Google Scholar
Gilligan Thomas, and Keith Krehbiel. 1989. “Asymmetric Information and Legislative Rules with a Heterogeneous Committee.” American Journal of Political Science 33 (May): 45990.Google Scholar
Gilligan Thomas, and Keith Krehbiel. 1990. “Organization of Informative Committees by a Rational Legislature.” American Journal of Political Science 34 (May): 53164.Google Scholar
Hamilton Alexander, James Madison, and John Jay [1788] 1961. The Federalist: The famous papers on the principles of American government, ed. Benjamin F. Wright, New York: Metrobooks.
Huber John, and Charles Shipan. 2002. Deliberate Discretion? The Institutional Foundations of Bureaucratic Autonomy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Krishna Vijay, and John Morgan. 2001. “Asymmetric Information and Legislative Rules: Some Amendments.” American Political Science Review 95 (June): 43552.Google Scholar
Mas-Colell Andreau, Michael Whinston, and Jerry Green. 1995. Microeconomic Theory. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
McCubbins Mathew, and Thomas Schwartz. 1984. “Congressional Oversight Overlooked: Police Patrols versus Fire Alarms.” American Journal of Political Science 2 (February): 16579.Google Scholar
McNollGast. 1987. “Administrative Procedures as Instruments of Political Control.” Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 3 (Fall): 24377.Google Scholar
Simon Herbert, Donald Smithburg, and Victor Thompson. 1950. Public Administration. New York: Knopf.
Wilson James Q. 1989. Bureaucracy: What Government Agencies Do and Why They Do It. New York: Basic Books.