Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-42gr6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-23T17:59:47.927Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

History as a laboratory to better understand the formation of institutions

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 May 2014

BAS VAN BAVEL*
Affiliation:
Department of History, Utrecht University, Utrecht, the Netherlands

Abstract

A main instrument for better understanding the formation of institutions, and explaining the differences in their long-run development between periods and societies, would be to use history as a laboratory, allowing us to test the hypotheses developed in the social sciences. This paper discusses the study by Douglas Allen, The Institutional Revolution, in that context, in order to identify some of the pitfalls in the current attempts by economists to use historical analysis. Next, the paper places his English case into a comparative perspective, helped by the recent insights gained by economic and social history, to see how these pitfalls can be avoided. Based on this, I argue for comparisons at the regional, national and global levels, and for a multidimensional view which includes social contextualization, combined with an open eye for discontinuity in long-run patterns, in order to avoid one-dimensional and teleological approaches to institutional change.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Millennium Economics Ltd 2014 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Acemoglu, D. and Johnson, J. A., and Robinson, S. (2005) ‘Institutions as a Fundamental Cause of Long-Run Growth’, Handbook of Economic Growth, 1A: 386472.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D. and Robinson, J. A. (2012), Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity, and Poverty, New York: Crown Business.Google Scholar
Allen, R. C. (2001), ‘The great divergence in European wages and prices from the Middle Ages to the First World War’, Explorations in Economic History, 38: 411447.Google Scholar
Allen, D. (2012), The Institutional Revolution. Measurement and the Economic Emergence of the Modern World, Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Avant, D. D. (2005), The Market for Force. The Consequences of Privatizing Security, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Brenner, R. and Isett, C. (2002), ‘England's Divergence from China's Yangzi Delta: Property Relations, Microeconomics, and Patterns of Development’, The Journal of Asian Studies, 61 (2): 609662.Google Scholar
Broadberry, S. N., Campbell, B., Klein, A., Overton, A., and van Leeuwen, B. (2011), ‘British Economic Growth, 1270–1870: An Output Based Approach’, paper London School of Economics, RePEc:ukc:ukcedp:1203.Google Scholar
Caferro, W. (1998), Mercenary Companies and the Decline of Siena, Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. (1960), ‘The Problem of Social Costs’, Journal of Law and Economics, 3: 144.Google Scholar
de Keyzer, M. (2013), ‘The Impact of Different Distributions of Power on Access Rights: The Campine Area, Brecklands and Geest Region Compared’, JoIE, 9 (4): 517542.Google Scholar
De Moor, T. (2008), ‘The Silent Revolution: A New Perspective on the Emergence of Commons, Guilds, and Other Forms of Corporate Collective Action in Western Europe’, The International Review of Social History, 53(Suppl. 16): 175208.Google Scholar
Demsetz, H. (1967), ‘Toward a Theory of Property Rights’, The American Economic Review, 57: 347359.Google Scholar
de Vries, J. (1981), Barges and Capitalism: Passenger Transportation in the Dutch Economy, 1632–1839, Utrecht: HES.Google Scholar
de Vries, J. and van der Woude, A. M. (1997), The First Modern Economy. Success, Failure, and Perseverance of the Dutch Economy, 1500–1815, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Diamond, J. and Robinson, J. A. (2010), ‘Afterword: Using Comparative Methods in Studies of Human History’, in Diamond, J. and Robinson, J. A. (eds.), Natural Experiments in History, Cambridge: Belknap Press, pp. 267276.Google Scholar
Dohrn van Rossum, G. (1987), ‘The Diffusion of the Public Clocks in the Cities of Late Medieval Europe, 1300–1500’, in Lepetit, B. and Hoock, J. (eds.), La ville et l’innovation en Europe, Paris: Éditions de l'école des hautes études en sciences sociales, pp. 2943.Google Scholar
Gelderblom, O. (2013), Cities of Commerce: The Institutional Foundations of International Trade in the Low Countries 1250–1650, Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Greif, A. (1994), ‘On the Political Foundations of the Late Medieval Commercial Revolution: Genoa During the Twelfth and Thirteenth Centuries’, Journal of Economic History, 54: 271287.Google Scholar
Greif, A. (2002) ‘Institutions and Impersonal Exchange’, Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 158: 168204.Google Scholar
Hejeebu, S. and McCloskey, D. (1999), ‘The Reproving of Karl Polanyi’, Critical Review, 13 (3/4): 285314.Google Scholar
Henning, M., Stam, E., and Wenting, R. (2013), ‘Path Dependence Research in Regional Economic Development’, Regional Studies, 47 (8): 13481362.Google Scholar
Hudson, P. (1989), ‘The Regional Perspective’, in Hudson, P. (ed.), The Regions and Industries: A Perspective on the Industrial Revolution in Britain, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 538.Google Scholar
Jones, P. (1997), The Italian City-State: from Commune to Signoria, Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Jursa, M., (2014), ‘Factor Markets in Babylonia from the Late Seventh to the Third Century BC’, Journal of the Economic and Social History of the Orient, 57: 173202.Google Scholar
Kula, W. (1986), Measures and Men, Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Kuran, T. (2012), The Long Divergence. How Islamic Law Held Back the Middle East, Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Kuys, J. A. E. (1994), Drostambt en schoutambt. De Gelderse ambtsorganisatie in het kwartier van Zutphen (ca. 1200–1543), Hilversum: Verloren.Google Scholar
Landes, D. S. (1983), Revolution in Time: Clocks and the Making of the Modern World, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Landes, D. S. (2006), ‘Why Europe and the West? Why not China?Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20 (2): 322.Google Scholar
Langlois, R. N. (2013), ‘The Institutional Revolution: A Review Essay’, Review of Austrian Economics, 26: 383395.Google Scholar
Le Goff, J. (1963), ‘Le temps du travail dans la “crise du XIVe siècle”: du temps médiéval au temps moderne’, Le Moyen Age, 69, 597613.Google Scholar
Maddison, A. (2003), The World Economy: Historical Statistics, Paris: OECD.Google Scholar
Maddison, A. (2006), The World Economy: A Millennial Perspective, Paris: OECD.Google Scholar
Malanima, P. (2011), ‘The Long Decline of a Leading Economy: GDP in Central and Northern Italy, 1300–1913’, European Review of Economic History, 15: 169219.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCloskey, D. N. (2013), ‘A Neo-Institutionalism of Measurement, without Measurement. A Comment on Douglas Allen's The Institutional Revolution’, Review of Austrian Economics, 26: 363373.Google Scholar
Mokyr, J. and Espín-Sánchez, J.-A. (2013), ‘The Institutional Revelation. A Comment on Douglas W. Allen's The Institutional Revolution’, Review of Austrian Economics, 26: 375381.Google Scholar
North, D. C. (1990), Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
North, D. C., Wallis, J., and Weingast, B. R. (2009), Violence and Social Orders: A Conceptual Framework for Interpreting Recorded Human History, New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
North, D. C. and Weingast, B. R. (1989), ‘Constitutions and Commitment. The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England’, Journal of Economic History, 49: 803832.Google Scholar
Ogilvie, S. (2007), ‘”Whatever is, is Right”? Economic Institutions in Pre-Industrial Europe’, Economic History Review, 60: 649684.Google Scholar
Pomeranz, K. (2000), The Great Divergence: China, Europe, and the Making of the Modern World Economy, Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Pomeranz, K. (2008), ‘Land Markets in Late Imperial and Republican China’, Continuity and Change, 23 (1): 101150.Google Scholar
Saito, O. (2009), ‘Land, Labour and Market Forces in Tokugawa Japan’, Continuity and Change, 24: 169196.Google Scholar
Scott, J. C. (1998), Seeing Like a State. How Certain Schemes to Improve the Human Condition Have Failed, New Haven and London: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Shiba, Y. (1969), Commerce and Society in Sung China. Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Sosson, J. R. (1977), Les travaux publics de la ville de Bruges XlVe-XVe siècles. Les matériaux. Les hommes, Bruxelles: Credit communal de Belgique.Google Scholar
Stone, L. (1991), ‘History and Post-Modernism’, Past & Present, 131: 217218.Google Scholar
Storper, M. (1997), The Regional World: Territorial Development in a Global Economy, New York: The Guilford Press.Google Scholar
Tewes, L. (1987), Die Amts- und Pfandpolitik der Erzbischöfe von Köln im Spätmittelalter (1306–1463), Köln: Böhlau.Google Scholar
Violante, C. (1974), La società Milanese nell’età precomunale, Rome: Gius. Laterza & Figli.Google Scholar
Vries, P. (2001), ‘Are Coal and Colonies Really Crucial? Kenneth Pomeranz and the Great Divergence’, Journal of World History, 12: 407455.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
van Bavel, B. J. P. (2007), ‘The Transition in the Low Countries. Wage Labour as an Indicator of the Rise of Capitalism in the Countryside, 14th-17th Centuries’, Past & Present Supplement, 2: 286303.Google Scholar
van Bavel, B. J. P. (2010), Manors and Markets. Economy and Society in the Low Countries, 500–1600, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
van Bavel, B. J. P., Campopiano, M., and Dijkman, J. (2014), ‘Markets for Land, Lease, Labour and Capital in Early-Islamic Iraq, 600–1100 AD’, Journal of the Economic and Social History of the Orient, 57: 262289.Google Scholar
van Bavel, B. J. P., De Moor, T., and Van Zanden, J. L. (2009), ‘Factor Markets in Global Economic History’, Continuity & Change, 24: 921.Google Scholar
van Bavel, B. J. P., Dijkman, J., Kuijpers, E., and Zuijderduijn, J. (2012), ‘The Organisation of Markets as a Key Factor in the Rise of Holland from the Fourteenth to the Sixteenth Century: A Test Case for an Institutional Approach’, Continuity and Change, 27 (3): 347378.Google Scholar
van Dam, P. J. E. M. (2001), ‘Digging for a dike. Holland's Labor Market Ca. 1510’, in Hoppenbrouwers, P. and van Zanden, J. L. (eds.), Peasants into Farmers? Turnhout: Brepols, pp. 220255.Google Scholar
van Zanden, J. L. (1999), ‘The Paradox of the Marks. The Exploitation of Commons in the Eastern Netherlands, 1250–1850’, Agricultural History Review, 47: 125144.Google Scholar
van Zanden, J. L. (2009), The Long Road to the Industrial Revolution. The European Economy in a Global Perspective, 1000–1800, Leiden: Brill.Google Scholar
van Zanden, J. L. and Van Leeuwen, B. (2012), ‘Persistent but not Consistent: The Growth of National Income in Holland 1347–1807’, Explorations in Economic History, 49 (2): 119130.Google Scholar