Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-c4f8m Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-24T23:34:11.879Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Embedding organizational arrangements: towards a general model

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  06 June 2014

CLAUDE MÉNARD*
Affiliation:
Centre d’Economie de la Sorbonne, Université de Paris (Panthéon-Sorbonne), Paris, France

Abstract

Notwithstanding its major contributions, the ‘Williamsonian’ branch of New Institutional Economics suffers from black holes that recent developments have pinpointed. Rather than taking stock, this paper capitalizes on some of these developments to look ahead. Section 2 provides a reminder of the hard core of transaction cost economics (TCE) with an emphasis on problems that TCE has allowed to identify, particularly the richness of organizational arrangements, an issue that needs further investigation. Section 3 discusses how to better understand the embedment of organizational arrangements in their institutional environment. The concept of ‘meso-institutions’ is introduced as a mean to capture mechanisms providing the needed interface. Section 4 considers another neglected dimension that requires renewed attention: the interactions of organizational arrangements with technologies that partially define their setting. This paper proposes a roadmap to explore this issue, based on an ongoing research developed around the key concept of ‘criticality’. Section 5 concludes.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Millennium Economics Ltd 2014 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Acemoglu, D. and Robinson, J. A. (2012), Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity and Poverty, New York, NY: Crown Business.Google Scholar
Alchian, A. A. (1965), ‘Some Economics of Property Rights’, Il Politico, 30 (4): 816819. Economic Forces at Work [Reprint], Indianapolis: Liberty Press, 1977.Google Scholar
Arrunada, B. (2007), ‘Pitfalls to Avoid when Measuring Institutions: Is ‘Doing Business’ Damaging Business?’, Journal of Comparative Economics, 35 (4): 729747.Google Scholar
Baker, G., Gibbons, R., and Murphy, K. J. (2008), ‘Strategic Alliances: Bridges Between ‘Islands of Conscious Power’’, Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 22 (2): 146163.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benham, L. (2005), ‘Licit and Illicit Responses to Regulation’, in Ménard, C. and Shirley, M. (eds.), Handbook of New Institutional Economics, Dordrecht–Berlin–New York: Springer.Google Scholar
Bradach, J. L. (1997), ‘Using the Plural Form in the Management of Restaurant Chains’, Administrative Science Quarterly, 42: 276303.Google Scholar
Bradach, J. L. and Eccles, R. (1989), ‘Price, Authority, and Trust: From Ideal Types to Plural Forms’, Annual Review of Sociology, 15: 97118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coase, R. H. (1937), ‘The Nature of the Firm’, Economica, 2 (1): 386405.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. (1960), ‘The Problem of Social Cost’, Journal of Law and Economics, 3(October): 144.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. (1998), ‘New Institutional Economics’, American Economic Review, 88 (2): 7274.Google Scholar
Cooter, R. D. and Schäfer, H. B. (2012), Solomon's Knot. How Law Can End the Poverty of Nations, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Davis, L. E. and North, D. C. (1971), Institutional Change and American Economic Growth, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
DeMariz, C., Ménard, C., and Abeillé, B. (2014), Public Procurement Reforms in Africa: Challenges in Institutions and Governance, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Denzau, A. T. and North, D. C. (1994), ‘Shared Mental Models: Ideologies and Institutions’, Kyklos, 47 (1): 331.Google Scholar
Dutton, K., Thompson, S., and Barraclough, B. (1997), The Art of Control Engineering, Harlow (UK): Addison Wesley Longman.Google Scholar
Englander, E. J. (1988), ‘Technology and Oliver Williamson's Transaction Cost Economics’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 10 (3): 339353.Google Scholar
Estache, A. and Martimort, D. (1999), ‘Politics, Transaction Costs, and the Design of Regulatory Institutions’, Policy Research Working Paper Series 2073, Washington: The World Bank.Google Scholar
Finger, M., Groenewegen, J. P. M., and Künneke, R. W. (2005), ‘The Quest for Coherence between Technology and Institutions in Infrastructures’, Journal of Network Industries, 6: 227259.Google Scholar
Finger, M. and Kunneke, R. (Eds.) (2011), International Handbook Of Network Industries. The Liberalization of Infrastructure, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Furubotn, E. and Richter, R. (2005), Institutions and Economic Theory. The Contribution of the New Institutional Economics, Ann Arbor: The University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Glachant, J. M. and Lévêque, F. (eds.) (2009), Electricity Reform in Europe: Towards a Single Energy Market, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grandori, A. and Soda, G. (1995), ‘Inter-firm Networks: Antecedents, Mechanisms and Forms’, Organization Studies, 16 (2): 183214.Google Scholar
Greif, A. (2005), ‘Commitment, Coercion and Markets: The Nature and Dynamics of Institutions Supporting Exchange’, in Ménard, C. and Shirley, M. (eds.), Handbook of New Institutional Economics, Dordrecht–Berlin–New York: Springer.Google Scholar
Greif, A. (2006), Institutions and the Path to the Modern Economy: Lessons from Medieval Trade, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Grossman, S. J. and Hart, O. D. (1986), ‘The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration’, Journal of Political Economy, 94 (4): 691719.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hodgson, G. (2002), ‘The Legal Nature of the Firm and the Myth of the Firm-Market Hybrid’, International Journal of the Economics of Business, 9 (1): 3760.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. (2006), ‘What Are Institutions?’, Journal of Economic Issues, 40 (1): 125.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. (forthcoming), Conceptualizing Capitalism. Institutions, Evolution, Future.Google Scholar
Holmström, B. and Roberts, J. (1998), ‘The Boundaries of the Firm Revisited’, The Journal of Economic Perspective, 12 (4): 7394.Google Scholar
Joskow, P. L. (2005), ‘Vertical Integration’, in Ménard, C. and Shirley, M. (eds.), Handbook of New Institutional Economics, Dordrecht–Berlin–New York: Springer.Google Scholar
Klein, P. G. (2005), ‘The Make-or-Buy Decisions: Lessons from Empirical Studies’, in Ménard, C. and Shirley, M. (eds.), Handbook of New Institutional Economics, Dordrecht–Berlin–New York: Springer.Google Scholar
Klein, P. G. and Shelanski, H. (1995), ‘Empirical Research in Transaction Cost Economics: A Survey and Assesment’, Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 11 (2): 335361.Google Scholar
Kunneke, R. (2008), ‘Institutional Reform and Technological Practice: The Case of Electricity’, Industrial and Corporate Change, 17: 233265.Google Scholar
Kunneke, R., Groenewegen, J., and Ménard, C. (2010), ‘Aligning Modes of Organization with Technology: Critical Transactions in the Reform of Infrastructures’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 75 (3): 494505.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laffont, J. J. (2005), Regulation and Development, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Lafontaine, F. and Slade, M. (2007), ‘Vertical Integration and Firm Boundaries: The Evidence’, Journal of Economic Literature, 45: 629685.Google Scholar
Lakatos, I. (1976), Proofs and Refutations, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Langlois, R. N. (2010), ‘Economic Institutions and the Boundaries of Business Groups’, in Colpan, A. M., Hikino, T., and Lincoln, J. R. (eds.), Oxford Handbook of Business Groups, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Langlois, R. N. and Robertson, P. L. (1994), ‘Institutions, Inertia, and Changing Industrial Leadership’, Industrial and Corporate Change, 3 (2): 359378.Google Scholar
Langlois, R. N. and Robertson, P. L. (1995), Firms, Markets, and Economic Change: A Dynamic Theory of Business Institutions, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
LaPorta, R., Lopez-de-Silvanes, F., Shleifer, A., and Vishny, R. W. (1998), ‘Law and Finance’, Journal of Political Economy, 106 (6): 11131155.Google Scholar
Levy, B. and Spiller, P. (1994), ‘The Institutional Foundations of Regulatory Commitment’, Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 9(Fall): 201246.Google Scholar
Libecap, G. D. (2009), ‘Property Rights Allocation of Common Pool Resources, in Ménard, C. and Ghertman, M. (eds.), Regulation, Deregulation, Reregulation: Institutional Perspectives, Cheltenham-Northampton: Edward Elgar, chap. 2.Google Scholar
Libecap, G. D. (2014), ‘Addressing Global Externalities: Transaction Costs Considerations’, Journal of Economic Literature (forthcoming).Google Scholar
Ménard, C. (1995), ‘Markets as Institutions versus Organizations as Markets: Disentangling Some Fundamental Concepts’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 28 (3): 161182.Google Scholar
Ménard, C. (2006), ‘Challenges in New Institutional Economics’, in Bindsell, U., Haucap, J., and Wey, C. (eds.), Institutions in Perspective, Tubingen: Mohr-Siebeck, pp. 2133.Google Scholar
Ménard, C. (2010), ‘Hybrid Organizations’, in Klein, P. and Sykuta, M. (eds.), The Elgar Companion to Transaction Cost Economics, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, chap. 18, pp. 176184.Google Scholar
Ménard, C. (2013a), ‘Hybrid Modes of Organization. Alliances, Joint Ventures, Networks, and Other ‘Strange’ Animals’, in Gibbons, R. and Roberts, J. (eds.), The Handbook of Organizational Economics, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, chap. 26: pp. 10661108.Google Scholar
Ménard, C. (2013b), ‘Plural Forms of Organizations: Where do We Stand?’, Managerial and Decision Economics, 34(35): 124139.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ménard, C. and Damergy, G. (2014), ‘Hybrids within Hybrids: A Challenging Organizational Arrangement in the Airline Industry’, Working Paper, Centre d'Economie de la Sorbonne, April.Google Scholar
Ménard, C. and Du Marais, B. (2006), ‘Can We Rank Legal Systems According to their Economic Efficiency?’, in Nobel, P. and Gets, M. (eds.), New Frontiers of Law and Economics, Zurich: Schulthess, pp. 727.Google Scholar
Ménard, C. and Shirley, M. (eds.) (2005/2008), Handbook of New Institutional Economics, Dordrecht–Berlin–New York: Springer.Google Scholar
Ménard, C. and Shirley, M. (2014), ‘The Future of New Institutional Economics: From Early Intuitions to a New Paradigm?’, Journal of Institutional Economics, doi:10.1017/S174413741400006X.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ménard, C. and Yvrande, A. (2005), ‘Institutional Constraints and Organizational Change. The Case of the British Rail Reform’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 56 (4): 675699.Google Scholar
Monteverde, K. C. and Teece, D. J. (1982), ‘Suppliers Switching Costs and Vertical Integration in the Automobile Industry’, Bell Journal of Economics, 13 (1): 206213.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nelson, R. R. and Winter, S. G. (1982), An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change, Cambridge, MA: The Belknap Press of Harvard University.Google Scholar
North, D. C. (1981), Structure and Change in Economic History, New York, NY: Norton and Co.Google Scholar
North, D. C. (1990), Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
North, D. C. (2004), Understanding the Process of Economic Change, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
North, D. C., Wallis, J., and Weingast, B. (2009), Violence and Social Orders: A Conceptual Framework for Interpreting Recorded Human History, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Ostrom, E. (2005), ‘Doing Institutional Analysis: Digging Deeper than Markets and Hierarchies’, in Ménard, C. and Shirley, M. (eds.), Handbook of New Institutional Economics, Dordrecht–Berlin–New York: Springer.Google Scholar
Oxley, J. (1999), ‘Institutional Environment and the Mechanism of Governance: The Impact of Intellectual Property Protection on the Structure of Inter-firm Alliances’, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 38: 283309.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roe, M. (2000), Corporate Reorganization and Bankrupcy: Legal and Financial Materials, New York, NY: Foundation Press.Google Scholar
Roe, M. (2005), ‘The Institutions of Corporate Governance’, in Ménard, C. and Shirley, M. (eds.), Handbook of New Institutional Economics, Dordrecht–Berlin–New York: Springer.Google Scholar
Rubin, P. (1978), ‘The Theory of the Firm and the Structure of the Franchise Contract’, Journal of Law and Economics, 21 (1): 223233.Google Scholar
Sened, I. and Galiani, S. (Eds.) (2014), Institutions, Property Rights and Economic Growth: The Legacy of Douglass North, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Shelanski, H. and Klein, P. (1995), ‘Empirical Research in Transaction Costs Economics’, Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 11 (2): 335361.Google Scholar
Shirley, M. (1995), Bureaucrats in Business, Washington, DC: The World Bank.Google Scholar
Shirley, M. (Ed.) (2002), Thirsting for Efficiency: The Economics and Politics of Urban Water Reforms, Amsterdam: Elsevier-Pergamon.Google Scholar
Shirley, M. (2008), Institutions and Development, Cheltenham–Northampton: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Shleifer, A., Glaeser, E. L., La Porta, R., Lopez de Silanes, F., and Djankov, S. D. (2003), ‘The New Comparative Economics’, Journal of Comparative Economics, 31 (4): 595619.Google Scholar
Spiller, P. (2009), ‘An Institutional Theory of Public Contracts: Regulatory Implications’, in Ménard, C. and Ghertman, M. (eds.), Regulation, Deregulation, Reregulation. Institutional Perspectives, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Spiller, P. and Tommasi, M., (2005), ‘The Institutions of Regulation: An Application to Public Utilities’, in Ménard, C. and Shirley, M. (eds.), Handbook of New Institutional Economics, Dordrecht–Berlin–New York: Springer.Google Scholar
Spiller, P. and Tommasi, M. (2007), The Institutional Foundations of Public Policy in Argentina: A Transactions Cost Approach, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (1971), ‘The Vertical Integration of Production: Market Failure Considerations’, American Economic Review, 61(May): 112123.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (1975), Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications, New York, NY: The Free Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (1985), The Economic Institutions of Capitalism, New York, NY: The Free Press-Macmillan.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (1988), ‘Technology and Transaction Costs: A Reply,’ Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 10 (3): 355363.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (1991/1996), ‘Comparative Economic Organization: The Analysis of Discrete Structural Alternatives’, Administrative Science Quarterly, 36 (2): 269296, in The Mechanisms of Governance, Oxford: Oxford University Press, chap. 4.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (2000), ‘The New Institutional Economics: Taking Stock, Looking Ahead’, Journal of Economic Literature, 37 (3): 595613.Google Scholar