Hostname: page-component-7c8c6479df-nwzlb Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-03-28T17:43:44.057Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Bribe Payments and Innovation in Developing Countries: Are Innovating Firms Disproportionately Affected?

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  13 May 2014

Meghana Ayyagari
Affiliation:
ayyagari@gwu.edu, School of Business, George Washington University, 2201 G St NW, Washington, DC 20052
Asli Demirgüç-Kunt
Affiliation:
ademirguckunt@worldbank.org, Development Research Group, World Bank, 1818 H St NW, Washington, DC 20433
Vojislav Maksimovic
Affiliation:
vmax@rhsmith.umd.edu, Smith School of Business, University of Maryland, 4417 Van Munching Hall, College Park, MD 20742.
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Core share and HTML view are not available for this content. However, as you have access to this content, a full PDF is available via the ‘Save PDF’ action button.

Innovating firms pay more bribes than noninnovators across 25,000 firms in 57 countries. The difference is larger in countries with more bureaucratic regulation and weaker governance. Innovators that pay bribes do not receive better services and do not have greater propensity to engage in other illegal activities such as tax evasion. Thus, innovators are more likely to be victims of corruption than perpetrators. Our findings point to the challenges facing entrepreneurs in developing countries and are consistent with the view that rent seeking by government officials unlike private criminal activity is more likely to target innovators.

Type
Research Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Michael G. Foster School of Business, University of Washington 2014 

References

Acemoglu, D.; Aghion, P.; and Zilibotti, F.. “Distance to Frontier, Selection, and Economic Growth.” Journal of the European Economic Association, 4 (2006), 3774.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D., and Johnson, S.. “Unbundling Institutions.” Journal of Political Economy, 113 (2005), 949995.Google Scholar
Ades, A., and Di Tella, R.. “The New Economics of Corruption: A Survey and Some New Results.” Political Studies, 45 (1997), 496516. Reprinted in Political Corruption, Heywood, P., ed. Oxford, UK: Blackwell Publishers (1997).Google Scholar
Aghion, P.; Burgess, R.; Redding, S.; and Zilibotti, F.. “Entry Liberalization and Inequality in Industrial Performance.” Journal of the European Economic Association, 3 (2005), 291302.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aghion, P., and Durlauf, S., eds. Handbook of Economic Growth. Amsterdam, Netherlands: North-Holland Elsevier Publishers (2005).Google Scholar
Ahlin, C., and Pang, J.. “Are Financial Development and Corruption Control Substitutes in Promoting Growth?Journal of Development Economics, 86 (2008), 414433.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alm, J.; Jackson, B. R.; and McKee, M.. “Estimating the Determinants of Taxpayer Compliance with Experimental Data.” National Tax Journal, 45 (1992a), 107114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alm, J.; Jackson, B. R.; and McKee, M.. “Institutional Uncertainty and Taxpayer Compliance.” American Economic Review, 82 (1992b), 10181026.Google Scholar
Alm, J.; Jackson, B. R.; and McKee, M.. “Fiscal Exchange, Collective Decision Institutions, and Tax Compliance.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 22 (1993), 285303.Google Scholar
Alm, J.; McClelland, G. H.; and Schulze, W. D.. “Why Do People Pay Taxes?Journal of Public Economics, 48 (1992), 2148.Google Scholar
Ayyagari, M.; Demirgüç-Kunt, A.; and Maksimovic, V.. “How Important Are Financing Constraints? The Role of Finance in the Business Environment.” World Bank Economic Review, 22 (2008a), 483516.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ayyagari, M.; Demirgüç-Kunt, A.; and Maksimovic, V.. “How Well Do Institutional Theories Explain Firms’ Perceptions of Property Rights?Review of Financial Studies, 21 (2008b), 18331871.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ayyagari, M.; Demirgüç-Kunt, A.; and Maksimovic, V.. “Formal versus Informal Finance: Evidence from China.” Review of Financial Studies, 23 (2010), 30483097.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ayyagari, M.; Demirgüç-Kunt, A.; and Maksimovic, V.. “Firm Innovation in Emerging Markets, Role of Finance and Governance.” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 46 (2011), 15451580.Google Scholar
Ayyagari, M.; Demirgüç-Kunt, A.; and Maksimovic, V.. “Financing in Developing Countries.” In Handbook of the Economics of Finance, Vol. 2, Constantinides, G. M., Harris, M., and Stulz, R., eds. Amsterdam: Newnes Elsevier Publishers (2013).Google Scholar
Ayyagari, M.; Demirgüç-Kunt, A.; and Maksimovic, V.. “Who Creates Jobs in Developing Countries?Small Business Economics, 43 (2014), 7599.Google Scholar
Barth, J.; Lin, C.; Lin, P.; and Song, F.. “Corruption in Bank Lending to Firms: Cross-Country Micro Evidence on the Beneficial Role of Competition and Information Sharing.” Journal of Financial Economics, 91 (2009), 361388.Google Scholar
Baumol, W. The Free-Market Innovation Machine: Analyzing the Growth Miracle of Capitalism. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press (2002).Google Scholar
Beck, T.; Demirgüç-Kunt, A.; and Maksimovic, V.. “Financial and Legal Constraints to Firm Growth: Does Firm Size Matter?Journal of Finance, 60 (2005), 137177.Google Scholar
Beck, T.; Demirgüç-Kunt, A.; and Maksimovic, V.. “Financing Patterns around the World: Are Small Firms Different?Journal of Financial Economics, 89 (2008), 467487.Google Scholar
Berkowitz, D., and Li, W.. “Tax Rights in Transition Economies: A Tragedy of the Commons?Journal of Public Economics, 76 (2000), 369397.Google Scholar
Carlin, B.; Dorabantu, F.; and Viswanathan, S.. “Public Trust, the Law and Financial Investment.” Journal of Financial Economics, 92 (2009), 321341.Google Scholar
Cull, R., and Xu, L. C.. “Institutions, Ownership, and Finance: The Determinants of Profit Reinvestment among Chinese Firms.” Journal of Financial Economics, 77 (2005), 117146.Google Scholar
De Soto, H. The Other Path: The Invisible Revolution in the Third World. New York: Harper Collins (1989).Google Scholar
Djankov, S.; La Porta, R.; Lopez-de-Silanes, F.; and Shleifer, A.. “The Regulation of Entry.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117 (2002), 137.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Djankov, S.; La Porta, R.; Lopez-de-Silanes, F.; and Shleifer, A.. “Courts.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118 (2003), 453517.Google Scholar
Faccio, M. “Politically Connected Firms.” American Economic Review, 96 (2006), 369386.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fisman, R., and Svensson, J.. “Are Corruption and Taxation Really Harmful to Growth? Firm Level Evidence.” Journal of Development Economics, 83 (2007), 6375.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frye, T., and Shleifer, A.. “The Invisible Hand and the Grabbing Hand.” American Economic Review, 87 (1997), 354358.Google Scholar
Graham, J. R., and Harvey, C.. “The Theory and Practice of Corporate Finance: Evidence from the Field.” Journal of Financial Economics, 60 (2001), 187243.Google Scholar
Graham, J. R.; Harvey, C.; and Rajgopal, S.. “The Economic Implications of Corporate Financial Reporting.” Journal of Accounting and Economics, 40 (2005), 373.Google Scholar
Grossman, G. M., and Helpman, E.. “Quality Ladders in the Theory of Growth.” Review of Economic Studies, 58 (1991), 4361.Google Scholar
Guiso, L.; Sapienza, P.; and Zingales, L.. “Trusting the Stock Market.” Journal of Finance, 63 (2008), 25572600.Google Scholar
Hall, R. E., and Jones, C. I.. “Why Do Some Countries Produce So Much More Output per Worker than Others?Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114 (1999), 83116.Google Scholar
Hazari, R. K. The Structure of the Corporate Private Sector: A Study of Concentration, Ownership and Control. Bombay: Asia Publishing House (1966).Google Scholar
Hellman, J. S.; Jones, G.; and Kaufmann, D.. “Seize the State, Seize the Day: State Capture and Influence in Transition Economies.” Journal of Comparative Economics, 31 (2003), 751773.Google Scholar
Houston, J.; Lin, C.; and Ma, Y.. “Media Ownership, Concentration and Corruption in Bank Lending.” Journal of Financial Economics, 100 (2011), 326350.Google Scholar
Johnson, S.; Kaufmann, D.; and Zoido-Lobaton, P.. “Regulatory Discretion and Corruption.” American Economic Review (Papers and Proceedings), 88 (1998), 387392.Google Scholar
Kaufmann, D.; Kraay, A.; and Mastruzzi, M.. “Governance Matters VIII: Aggregate and Individual Governance Indicators, 1996–2008.” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 4978 (2009).Google Scholar
Kaufmann, D.; Montoriol-Garriga, J.; and Recanatini, F.. “How Does Bribery Affect Public Service Delivery? Micro-Evidence from Service Users and Public Officials in Peru.” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 4492 (2008).Google Scholar
Klapper, L.; Laeven, L.; and Rajan, R.. “Entry Regulation as a Barrier to Entrepreneurship.” Journal of Financial Economics, 82 (2006), 591629.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mauro, P. “Corruption and Growth.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110 (1995), 681712.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Menard, S. “Applied Logistic Regression Analysis.” Sage University Paper Series on Quantitative Applications in the Social Sciences, 07–106. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage (1995).Google Scholar
Michalopoulos, S.; Laeven, L.; and Levine, R.. “Financial Innovation and Endogenous Growth.” NBER Working Papers 15356 (2009).Google Scholar
Murphy, K.; Shleifer, A.; and Vishny, R.. “Why Is Rent-Seeking So Costly to Growth?American Economic Review, 83 (1993), 409414.Google Scholar
Olken, B., and Pande, R.. “Corruption in Developing Countries.” Annual Review of Economics, 4 (2012), 479509.Google Scholar
Papke, L. E., and Wooldridge, J. M.. “Econometric Methods for Fractional Response Variables with an Application to 401(k) Plan Participation Rates.” Journal of Applied Econometrics, 11 (1996), 619632.Google Scholar
Pommerehne, W.; Hart, A.; and Frey, B. S.. “Tax Morale, Tax Evasion and the Choice of Policy Instruments in Different Political Systems.” Public Finance, 49 (1994), 5269.Google Scholar
Scholz, J. T., and Lubell, M.. “Trust and Taxpayers: Testing the Heuristic Approach to Collective Action.” American Journal of Political Science, 42 (1998), 398417.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scholz, J. T., and Pinney, N.. “Duty, Fear and Tax Compliance: The Heuristic Basis of Citizenship Behavior.” American Journal of Political Science, 39 (1995), 490512.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J. A. The Theory of Economic Development. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press (1934).Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J. A. Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy. New York: Harper and Brothers (1942).Google Scholar
Segerstrom, P. S. “Innovation, Imitation, and Economic Growth.” Journal of Political Economy, 99 (1991), 807827.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shleifer, A., and Vishny, R. W.. “Corruption.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108 (1993), 599617.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, K. W. “Reciprocity and Fairness: Positive Incentives for Taxpayer Compliance.” In Why People Pay Taxes, Slemrod, J., ed. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press (1992).Google Scholar
Spicer, M. W., and Lundstedt, S. B.. “Understanding Tax Evasion.” Public Finance, 31 (1976), 295304.Google Scholar
Svensson, J. “Who Must Pay Bribes and How Much? Evidence from a Cross Section of Firms.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118 (2003), 207230.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Svensson, J. “Eight Questions about Corruption.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19 (2005), 1942.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Torgler, B. Tax Compliance and Tax Morale: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar (2007).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wooldridge, J. M. Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press (2002).Google Scholar
Supplementary material: PDF

Ayyagari Supplementary Material

Appendix

Download Ayyagari Supplementary Material(PDF)
PDF 43.3 KB