Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-cfpbc Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-16T16:05:23.926Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Sustainability and the measurement of wealth: further reflections

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  23 April 2013

Kenneth J. Arrow
Affiliation:
Stanford University, Department of Economics, USA. E-mail: arrow@stanford.edu
Partha Dasgupta
Affiliation:
Faculty of Economics, University of Cambridge; and Sustainable Consumption Institute, University of Manchester, UK. E-mail: partha.dasgupta@econ.cam.ac.uk
Lawrence H. Goulder
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Stanford University, Stanford, CA 94305, USA. E-mail: goulder@stanford.edu
Kevin J. Mumford
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Purdue University, USA. E-mail: mumford@purdue.edu
Kirsten Oleson
Affiliation:
Department of Natural Resources and Environmental Management, University of Hawaii, USA. E-mail: koleson@hawaii.edu

Abstract

The June 2012 issue of Environment and Development Economics published a symposium with considerable focus on our paper, ‘Sustainability and the measurement of wealth’. The Symposium also contained five articles in which other researchers offered valuable comments on our paper. The present note replies to those comments. It clarifies important issues and reveals how important questions relating to sustainability analysis can be fruitfully addressed within our framework. These include questions about the treatment of time, the use of shadow prices and the treatment of transnational externalities. This note also offers new theoretical results that help substantiate our earlier empirical finding that the value of human health is something very different from the value of the consumption permitted by health and survival.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2013 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Arrow, K.J., Dasgupta, P., Goulder, L.H., Mumford, K.J., and Oleson, K. (2012), ‘Sustainability and the measurement of wealth’, Environment and Development Economics 17(3): 317353.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barnett, H.J. and Morse, C. (1963), Scarcity and Growth, Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Collins, S. and Bosworth, B. (1996), ‘Economic growth in East Asia: accumulation versus assimilation’, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2: 135191.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dasgupta, P. (1990), ‘The environment as a commodity’, Oxford Review of Economic Policy 6(1): 5167.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dasgupta, P. and Mäler, K.-G. (2000), ‘Net national product, wealth, and social well-being’, Environment and Development Economics 5(1): 6993.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Duraiappah, A. and Munoz, P. (2012), ‘Inclusive wealth: a tool for the United Nations’, Environment and Development Economics 17(3): 362367.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ferraro, P.J., Lawlor, K., Mullan, K.L., and Pattanayak, S.K. (2012), ‘Forest figures: ecosystem services valuation and policy evaluation in developing countries’, Review of Environmental Economics and Policy 6(1): 2044.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gundimeda, H. and Shyamsundar, P. (2012), ‘Forests, sustainability, and poverty in India’, Environment and Development Economics 17(3): 373378.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hall, R.E. and Jones, C. (1999), ‘Why do some countries produce so much more output per worker than others?’, Quarterly Journal of Economics 114: 83116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, K. (2012), ‘Comments on Arrow et al.., “Sustainability and the measurement of wealth”?’, Environment and Development Economics 17(3): 356361.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, K. and Clemens, M. (1999), ‘Genuine savings rates in developing countries’, World Bank Economic Review 13(2): 333356.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hotelling, H. (1931), ‘The economics of exhaustible resources’, Journal of Political Economy 39(2): 137175.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meade, J.E. (1955), Trade and Welfare, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Nordhaus, W.D. and Boyer, J. (2000), Warming of the World: Economic Models of Global Warming, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pattanayak, S.K. (2004), ‘Valuing watershed services: concepts and empirics from Southeast Asia’, Agriculture, Ecosystems & Environment 104(1): 171184.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Perry, C. (2012), ‘Accounting for water: stocks, flows, and values’, in UNU-IHDP/UNEP, Inclusive Wealth Report 2012, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Smulders, S. (2012), ‘An arrow in the Achilles' heel of sustainability and wealth accounting’, Environment and Development Economics 17(3): 368372.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Solow, R. (2012), ‘A few comments on “sustainability and the measurement of wealth”?’, Environment and Development Economics 17(3): 354355.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
UNU-IHDP/UNEP (2012), Inclusive Wealth Report 2012, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Viscusi, W.K. and Aldy, J.E. (2003), ‘The value of a statistical life: a critical review of market estimates throughout the world’, Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 27(1): 576.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vouvaki, D. and Xepapadeas, A. (2009), ‘Total factor productivity growth when factors of production generate environmental externalities’, Working Paper No. 20-2009, FEEM, Milan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
World Bank (2011), The Changing Wealth of Nations, Washington, DC: World Bank.Google Scholar