Hostname: page-component-7c8c6479df-8mjnm Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-03-29T10:08:07.470Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

QUANTIFYING THE IMPACT OF PARTIAL INFORMATION ON SHARPE RATIO OPTIMIZATION

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 March 2013

Lihong Zhang
Affiliation:
School of Economics and Management, Tsinghua University, Beijing 100084, PRC E-mail: zhanglh2@sem.tsinghua.edu.cn
Lin Zhao
Affiliation:
Academy of Mathematics and Systems Science, Chinese Academy of Sciences, Beijing 100190, PRC E-mail: zhaolin@iss.ac.cn

Abstract

Motivated by the fact that many investors have limited ability to update the expectation regarding future stock returns with the arrival of new information instantly, this paper provides a continuous-time model to study the performance of passive trading strategies. We derive the true Sharp ratio of the passive strategies in terms of the mean and variance of an explicit stochastic process. Based on this expression, we quantify the impact of partial information by performing a thorough comparative static analysis. Such an analysis provides a rationale for why investors with inaccurate information about stock return behave better in the mean-reverting environment than in the i.i.d. environment and why pessimistic investors can achieve better performance than optimistic ones. As a by-product, we propose an analytical approach to compute the “implied” parameters in stock return predictor for both i.i.d. and mean-reverting dynamics, which seems interesting for future research.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2013 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1.Bajeux-Besnainou, I. & Portait, R. (1998). Dynamic asset allocation in a mean-variance framework. Management Science 44: 7995.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
2.Barberis, N. (2000). Investing for the long run when returns are predictable. Journal of Finance 55: 225264.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
3.Braun, M. & Larrain, B. (2005). Finance and the business cycle: international, inter-industry evidence. Journal of Finance 60: 10971128.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
4.Brennan, M.J. (1998). The role of learning in dynamic portfolio decisions. European Economic Review 1: 295306.Google Scholar
5.Brennan, M.J., Schwartz, E.S., & Lagnado, R. (1997). Strategic asset allocation. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 21: 13771403.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
6.Caliendo, F. & Huang, K. (2008). Overconfidence and consumption over the life cycle. Journal of Macroeconomics 30: 13471369.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
7.Campbell, J.Y. & Viceira, L.M. (1999). Consumption and portfolio decisions when expected returns are time-varying. Quarterly Journal of Economics 114: 433495.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
8.Cvitanić, J., Lazrakb, A., & Wang, T. (2008). Implications of the Sharpe ratio as a performance measure in multi-period settings. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 32: 16221649.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
9.Cvitanić, J., Lazrakb, A., Martellini, L., & Zapatero, F. (2006). Dynamic portfolio choice with parameter uncertainty and the economic value of analysts’ recommendations. Review of Financial Studies 19: 11131156.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
10.David, A. (1997). Fluctuating confidence in stock markets: implications for returns and volatility. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 32: 427462.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
11.Detemple, J.B. (1986). Asset pricing in a production economy with incomplete information. Journal of Finance 41: 383391.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
12.Dothan, M.U. & Feldman, D. (1986). Equilibrium interest rates and multi-period bonds in a partially observable economy. Journal of Finance 41: 369382.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
13.Duffie, D. (1992). Dynamic asset pricing theory. Princeton, NJ: University Press.Google Scholar
14.Epstein, L.G. & Schneider, M. (2007). Learning under ambiguity. Review of Economic Studies 74: 12751303.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
15.Epstein, L.G. & Wang, T. (1994). Inter-temporal asset pricing under Knightian uncertainty. Econometrica 62: 283322.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
16.Feldman, D. (1992). Logarithmic preferences, myopic decisions, and incomplete information. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 27: 619629.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
17.Gennotte, G. (1986). Optimal portfolio choice under incomplete information. Journal of Finance 41: 733749.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
18.Gomes, F.J. (2007). Exploiting short-run predictability. Journal of Banking and Finance 31: 14271440.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
19.Kim, T.S. & Omberg, E. (1996). Dynamic non-myopic portfolio behavior. Review of Financial Studies 9: 141161.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
20.Kogan, L., Ross, S.A., Wang, J., & Westerfield, M.M. (2006). The price impact and survival of irrational traders. Journal of Finance 61: 195229.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
21.Korn, R. & Trautmann, S. (1995). Continuous-time portfolio optimization under terminal wealth constraints. ZOR 42: 6993.Google Scholar
22.Leippold, M., Trojani, F., & Vanini, P. (2008). Learning and asset prices under ambiguous information. Review of Financial Studies 21: 25652597.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
23.Li, D. & Ng, W.L. (2000). Optimal dynamic portfolio selection: multi-period mean-variance formulation. Mathematical Finance 10: 387406.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
24.Liptser, R.S. & Shiryayev, A.N. (1977). Statistics of Random Processes I and II. New York: Springer.Google Scholar
25.Merton, R.C. (1980). On estimating the expected return on the market: an exploratory investigation. Journal of Financial Economics 8: 323362.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
26.Merton, R.C. (1992). Continuous-time finance. Cambridge, MA: B. Blackwell, revised edition.Google Scholar
27.Modigliani, F. & Modigliani, L. (1997). Risk-adjusted performance. Journal of Portfolio Management 23: 4554.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
28.Pástor, Ľ. & Veronesi, P. (2003). Stock valuation and learning about profitability. Journal of Finance 58: 17491789.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
29.Peng, L. (2005). Learning with information capacity constraints. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 40: 307329.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
30.Peng, L. & Xiong, L. (2006). Investor attention, overconfidence and category learning. Journal of Financial Economics 80: 563602.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
31.Sharpe, W. (1966). Mutual fund performance. Journal of Business 39: 119138.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
32.Sharpe, W. (1994). The Sharpe ratio. Journal of Portfolio Management 21: 4958.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
33.Veronesi, P. (2000). How does information quality affect stock returns? Journal of Finance 55: 807837.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
34.Wachter, J.A. (2002). Portfolio and consumption decisions under mean-reverting returns: an exact solution for complete markets. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 37: 6391.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
35.Xia, Y.H. (2001). Learning about predictability: the effects of parameter uncertainty on dynamic asset allocation. Journal of Finance 56: 205246.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
36.Xiong, J. & Zhou, X.Y. (2007). Mean-variance portfolio selection under partial information. SIAM Journal on Control and Optimization 46: 156175.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
37.Zhao, Y.G. & Ziemba, W.T. (2002). Mean-variance versus expected utility in dynamic investment analysis. Computational Management Science 8: 322.Google Scholar