Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-2lccl Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-26T13:20:50.349Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Domestic Politics of the International Dollar Standard: A Statistical Analysis of Support for the Reserve Currency, 2000–2008

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 May 2013

Victor Shih*
Affiliation:
University of California, San Diego
David A. Steinberg*
Affiliation:
University of Oregon
*
Victor Shih, School of International Relations and Pacific Studies, University of California, San Diego, 9500 Gilman Drive, La Jolla, CA 92093-0519
David A. Steinberg, University of Oregon, Department of Political Science, 1284University of Oregon, Eugene, OR 97403, email: blogs.uoregon.edu/davidsteinberg/

Abstract

Abstract. Why did most central banks continue to purchase dollar reserves during the 2000s even though they suffered mounting financial losses as a result of this policy? This paper argues that domestic political considerations determine whether policy makers accumulate or dump the reserve currency. We hypothesize that central bank independence decreases support for the dollar because independent central banks reduce the political clout of exporters and increase the salience of financial performance. This argument is tested using data on countries' holdings of US Treasury securities between 2000 and 2008. The statistical results indicate that countries with independent central banks were more likely to sell and less likely to purchase US treasuries. Our findings suggest that a complete understanding of the international dollar standard requires greater attention to domestic politics and how political institutions influence the balance of power between competing interest groups.

Résumé. Pourquoi est-ce que la plupart des banques centrales ont continué à acheter des réserves de dollars au cours des années 2000, même quand ils souffraient des pertes financières en raison de cette politique? Cet article soutient que des considérations de politiques nationale déterminent si les responsables des politiques décident d'accumuler ou de vider leurs monnaie de réserve. Nous émettons l'hypothèse que l'indépendance de la banque centrale décourage le soutien pour le dollar, car les banques centrales indépendantes réduise la puissance politique des exportateurs et augmente l'importance de la performance financière. Cet argument est testé en utilisant des données sur la quantité de titres du Trésor américain possédée par pays entre 2000 et 2008. Les résultats statistiques démontrent que les pays avec des banques centrales indépendantes étaient plus susceptibles de vendre et moins susceptibles d'acheter des obligations du Trésor américain. Nos résultats suggèrent qu'une compréhension complète de l'étalon dollar international exige une plus grande attention à la politique nationale, et comment les institutions politiques influencent l'équilibre du pouvoir entre les groupes d'intérêts concurrents.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Canadian Political Science Association 2012

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Aizenman, J. and Lee, J.. 2007. “International Reserves: Precautionary versus Mercantilist Views, Theory and Evidence.” Open Economies Review 18: 191214.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baines, A. 2001. “Capital Mobility, Perspectives, and Central Bank Independence.” Policy Sciences 34: 171–93.Google Scholar
Bank of Belgium. 2008. “Frequently Asked Questions.” www.bnb.be/pub/FAQ.htm. Accessed on April 30, 2008.Google Scholar
Barro, R. J. and Sala-i-Martin, X.. 1998. Economic Growth. Cambridge MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Bearce, D. H. 2008. “Not Complements, but Substitutes: Fixed Exchange Rate Commitments, Central Bank Independence and External Currency Stability.” International Studies Quarterly 52: 807–24.Google Scholar
Beck, N. 2001. “Time-Series—Cross-Sectional Data: What Have We Learned in the Past Few Years?Annual Review of Political Science 4: 271–93.Google Scholar
Beck, N. and Katz, J.N.. 1995. “What To Do (and Not To Do) with Time-Series Cross-Section Data.” American Political Science Review 89: 634–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beck, T., Demirgüç-Kunt, A. and Levine, R.. 2010. “Financial Institutions and Markets across Countries and over Time.” World Bank Economic Review 24: 7792.Google Scholar
Beim, D. and Calomiris, C.. 2001. Emerging Financial Markets. Boston: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Bowles, P. and Wang, B.. 2008. “The Rocky Road Ahead: China, the US and the Future of the Dollar.” Review of International Political Economy 15: 335–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Broz, J.L. 2002. “Political System Transparency and Monetary Commitment Regimes.” International Organization 56 (4): 861–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chinn, M. and Frankel, J.. 2005. “Will the Euro Eventually Surpass the Dollar as Leading International Reserve Currency?” NBER Working Paper Series, no. 11510.Google Scholar
Chinn, M. and Ito, H.. 2006. “What Matters for Financial Development?Journal of Development Economics 61: 163–92.Google Scholar
Cohen, B.J. 1998. The Geography of Money. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Cohen, B.J. 2009. “Toward a Leaderless Currency System.” In The Future of the Dollar, ed. Helleiner, E. and Kirshner, J.. Ithaca NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Copelovitch, M. and Singer, D.A.. 2008. “Financial Regulation, Monetary Policy, and Inflation in the Industrialized World.” Journal of Politics 70: 663–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crowe, C. and Meade, E.. 2008. “Central bank independence and transparency.” European Journal of Political Economy 24: 763–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cukierman, A., Webb, S. and Neyapti, B.. 1992. “Measuring the Independence of Central Banks and Its Effects on Policy Outcomes.” World Bank Economic Review 6: 353–98.Google Scholar
Dooley, M.P., Folkerts-Landau, D. and Garber, P.. 2003. “An Essay on the Revived Bretton Woods System.” NBER Working Paper Series, no. 9971.Google Scholar
Dooley, M.P., Folkerts-Landau, D. and Garber, P.. 2004. “The Revived Bretton Woods System.” NBER Working Paper Series, no. 10332.Google Scholar
Dooley, M. and Garber, P.. 2005. “Is it 1958 or 1968? Three Notes on the Longevity of the Revived Bretton Woods SystemBrookings Papers on Economic Activity 1: 147–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eichengreen, B. 2007. Global Imbalances and the Lessons of Bretton Woods. Cambridge MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Eichengreen, B. 2011. Exorbitant Privilege: The Rise and Fall of the Dollar and the Future of the International Monetary System. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Frankel, J. 1995. “Still the Lingua Franca: The Exaggerated Death of the Dollar.” Foreign Affairs 74: 916.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frieden, J.A. 1991. “Invested Interests: The Politics of National Economic Policies in a World of Global Finance.” International Organization 45: 425–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gartzke, E. 2006. “The Affinity of Nations Index, 1946–2002.” Version 4.0. http://dss.ucsd.edu/~egartzke/ (March 9, 2010).Google Scholar
Goodman, J. 1991. “The Politics of Central Bank Independence.” Comparative Politics 23: 329349.Google Scholar
Grimes, W. 2009. Currency and Contest in East Asia: the Great Power Politics of Financial Regionalism. Ithaca NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Helleiner, E. 2009. “Enduring Top Currency, Fragile Negotiated Currency: Politics and the Dollar's International Role.” In The Future of the Dollar, ed. Helleiner, E. and Kirshner, J.. Ithaca NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Helleiner, E. 2010. “The New Politics of Global Reserve ReformJournal of Globalization and Development 1 (2): 112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Helleiner, E., and Malkin, A.. 2012. “Sectoral Interests and Global Money: Renminbi, Dollars, and the Domestic Foundations of International Currency Policy.” Open Economies Review 23: 3355.Google Scholar
Henning, C.R. 1994. Currencies and Politics in the United States, Germany and Japan. Washington: Institute for International Economics.Google Scholar
Henning, C.R. 2006. “The Exchange-Rate Weapon and Macroeconomic Conflict.” In International Monetary Power, ed. Andrews, D.M.. Ithaca NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Higgins, M. and Klitgaard, T.. 2004. “Reserve Accumulation.” Current Issues in Economics and Finance 10: 18.Google Scholar
Ilzetzki, E., Reinhart, C. and Rogoff, K.. 2008. “Exchange Rate Arrangements Entering the 21st Century.” http://terpconnect.umd.edu/~creinhar/Papers.html (March 15, 2010)Google Scholar
Johnson, J. 2008. “Forbidden Fruit: Russia's Uneasy Relationship with the US Dollar.” Review of International Political Economy 15: 379–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Katada, S. 2008. “From a Supporter to a Challenger? Japan's Currency Leadership in Dollar-Dominated East Asia.” Review of International Political Economy 15: 399417.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kirshner, J. 2009. “After the (Relative) Fall.” In The Future of the Dollar, ed. Helleiner, E. and Kirshner, J.. Ithaca NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Laeven, L. and Valencia, F.. 2008. “Systemic Banking Crises: A New Database.” IMF Working Papers 08/224.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lake, D. 2009. “Open Economy Politics: A Critical Review.” Review of International Organizations 4: 219–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Liew, L. and Wu, H.. 2007. The Making of China's Exchange Rate Policy. Cheltenham UK: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
McKinnon, R. 2001. “The International Dollar Standard and the Sustainability of the US Current Account Deficit.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1: 227–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McKinnon, R. 2009. “US Current Account Deficits and the Dollar Standard's Sustainability.” In The Future of the Dollar, ed. Helleiner, E. and Kirshner, J.. Ithaca NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
McNamara, K. 2002. “Rational Fictions: Central Bank Independence and the Social Logic of Delegation.” West European Politics 25: 4776.Google Scholar
McNamara, K. 2008. “A Rivalry in the Making? The Euro and International Monetary Power.” Review of International Political Economy 15: 439–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olson, M. 1965. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Cambridge MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Oye, K. 1985. “The Sterling-Dollar-Franc Triangle: Monetary Diplomacy 1929–1937.” World Politics 38: 173–99.Google Scholar
Pauly, L. 2006. “Monetary Statecraft in Follower States.” In International Monetary Power, ed. Andrews, D.M.. Ithaca NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Pineau, G.et al. 2006. The Accumulation of Foreign Reserves. European Central Bank Occasional Paper Series, no. 43.Google Scholar
Plümper, T. and Troeger, V.. 2007. “Efficient Estimation of Time-Invariant and Rarely Changing Variables in Finite Sample Panel Analyses with Unit Fixed Effects.” Political Analysis 15: 124–39.Google Scholar
Plümper, T., Troeger, V. and Manow, P.. 2005. “Panel Data Analysis in Comparative Politics: Linking Method to Theory.” European Journal of Political Research 44 (2): 327–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Polillo, S. and Guillén, M.. 2005. “Globalization Pressures and the State: The Worldwide Spread of Central Bank Independence.” American Journal of Sociology 110: 17641802.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posen, A. 1995. “Declarations are not Enough: Financial Sector Sources of Central Bank Independence.” NBER Macroeconomics Annual 10: 253–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rodrik, D. 2006. “Social Cost of Foreign Exchange Reserves.” International Economic Journal 20: 253–66.Google Scholar
Roubini, N. and Mihm, S.. 2010. Crisis Economics. New York: Penguin Press.Google Scholar
Roubini, N. and Setser, B.. 2005. “Will the Bretton Woods 2 Regime Unravel Soon?” Paper presented at the Symposium on the Revived Bretton Woods System, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Feb. 4.Google Scholar
Scheller, H. 2004. The European Central Bank. Frankfurt: European Central Bank.Google Scholar
Schwartz, H. 2009. Subprime Nation: American Power, Global Capital, and the Housing Bubble. Ithaca NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Simmons, B. 1994. Who Adjusts? Domestic Sources of Foreign Economic Policy during the Interwar Years. Princeton NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Simmons, B. 1996. “Rulers of the Game: Central Bank Independence during the Interwar Years.” International Organization 50: 407–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sobol, D. 1998. “Foreign Ownership of US Treasury Securities.” Current Issues in Economics and Finance 4: 16.Google Scholar
Standard Chartered. 2007. On the Ground. January 5.Google Scholar
Standard Chartered. 2008. PBoC Sterilisation Update. June 18.Google Scholar
Steinberg, D. and Shih, V.. 2012. “Interest Group Influence in Authoritarian States: The Political Determinants of Chinese Exchange Rate Policy.” Comparative Political Studies 45: 1404–33.Google Scholar
Wacziarg, R. and Welch, K.E.. 2008. “Trade Liberalization and Growth: New Evidence.” World Bank Economic Review 22 (2): 187231.Google Scholar
Walsh, C.E. 2005. “Central Bank Independence.” In The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, ed. Durlauf, S. and Blume, L.. Basingstoke UK: Nature Publishing Group.Google Scholar
Walter, A. 2006. “Domestic Sources of International Monetary Leadership.” In International Monetary Power, ed. Andrews, D.M.. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Willett, T.D. 1980. International Liquidity Issues. Washington, D.C.: American Enterprise Institute Press.Google Scholar
Woolley, J. 1986. Monetary Politics: The Federal Reserve and the Politics of Monetary Policy. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
World Development Indicators Database, The World Bank.Google Scholar
Wright, L. 2009. “The Elusive Price for Stability: Ideas and Interests in the Reform of China's Exchange Rate.” Doctoral dissertation, George Washington University, Washington DC.Google Scholar