Hostname: page-component-7c8c6479df-xxrs7 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-03-27T17:05:28.370Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Does religiosity promote property rights and the rule of law?

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 February 2013

NICLAS BERGGREN*
Affiliation:
Research Institute of Industrial Economics (IFN), Stockholm, Sweden; and Department of Institutional Economics, University of Economics in Prague, Prague, Czech Republic
CHRISTIAN BJØRNSKOV
Affiliation:
Department of Economics and Business, Aarhus University, Aarhus, Denmark

Abstract

Social and cultural determinants of economic institutions and outcomes have come to the forefront of economic research. We introduce religiosity, measured as the share for which religion is important in daily life, to explain institutional quality in the form of property rights and the rule of law. Previous studies have only measured the impact of membership shares of different religions, with mixed results. We find, in a cross-country regression analysis comprising up to 112 countries, that religiosity is negatively related to our institutional outcome variables. This only holds in democracies (not autocracies), which suggests that religiosity affects the way institutions work through the political process. Individual religions are not related to our measures of institutional quality.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Millennium Economics Ltd 2013

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Acemoglu, D. and Johnson, S. (2005), ‘Unbundling Institutions’, Journal of Political Economy, 113 (5): 949995.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., and Robinson, J. A. (2005), ‘Institutions as a Fundamental Cause of Long-run Growth’, in Aghion, P. and Durlauf, S. N. (eds.), Handbook of Economic Growth: Volume 1A, Amsterdam: Elsevier, pp. 385472.Google Scholar
Aghion, P., Alesina, A., and Trebbi, F. (2004), ‘Endogenous Political Institutions’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119 (2): 565611.Google Scholar
Alesina, A., Devleeschauwer, A., Easterly, W., Kurlat, S., and Wazciarg, R. (2003), ‘Fractionalization’, Journal of Economic Growth, 8 (2): 155194.Google Scholar
Ayyagari, M., Demirgüç-Kunt, A., and Maksimovic, V. (2006), ‘How Well Do Institutional Theories Explain Firms’ Perceptions of Property Rights?’, Review of Financial Studies, 21 (4): 18331871.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baier, C. J. and Wright, B. R. E. (2001), ‘“If You Love Me, Keep My Commandments”: A Meta-Analysis of the Effect of Religion on Crime’, Journal of Research in Crime and Delinquency, 38 (1): 321.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barro, R. J. and McCleary, R. M. (2005), ‘Which Countries Have State Religions?’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120 (4): 13311370.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berggren, N. (1997), ‘Rhetoric or Reality? An Economic Analysis of the Effects of Religion in Sweden’, Journal of Socio-Economics, 26 (6): 571596.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berggren, N. and Bjørnskov, C. (2011), ‘Is the Importance of Religion in Daily Life Related to Social Trust? Evidence from Cross-Country and Cross-State Comparisons’, Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 80 (3): 459480.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berggren, N. and Jordahl, H. (2005), ‘Does Free Trade Really Reduce Growth? Further Testing Using the Economic Freedom Index’, Public Choice, 122 (1–2): 99114.Google Scholar
Besley, T., Persson, T., and Sturm, D. M. (2010), ‘Political Competition, Policy and Growth: Theory and Evidence from the U.S. States’, Review of Economic Studies, 77 (4): 13291352.Google Scholar
Bjørnskov, C. (2008), ‘The Growth–Inequality Association: Government Ideology Matters’, Journal of Development Economics, 87 (2): 300308.Google Scholar
Bjørnskov, C. (2010), ‘How Does Social Trust Lead to Better Governance? An Attempt to Separate Electoral and Bureaucratic Mechanisms’, Public Choice, 144 (1–2): 323346.Google Scholar
Brambor, T., Clark, W. R., and Golder, M. (2006), ‘Understanding Interaction Models: Improving Empirical Analysis’, Political Analysis, 14 (1): 6382.Google Scholar
Cheibub, J. A., Gandhi, J., and Vreeland, J. R. (2010), ‘Democracy and Dictatorship Revisited’, Public Choice, 143 (1–2): 67101.Google Scholar
CIA (2010), CIA World Factbook 2010, Langley, VA: Central Intelligence Agency.Google Scholar
Dunning, T. (2008), ‘Model Specification in Instrumental-Variables Regression’, Political Analysis, 16 (3): 290302.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Durlauf, S. N., Kourtellos, A., and Tan, C. M. (2011), ‘Is God in the Details? A Reexamination of the Role of Religion in Economic Growth’, Journal of Applied Econometrics, 27 (7): 10591075.Google Scholar
Fere, S. and Klanjšek, R. (2009), ‘Cross-Cultural Insight into the Association between Authoritarianism and Religiousness’, Archives for the Psychology of Religion, 31 (2): 177190.Google Scholar
Gallup (2009), ‘Gallup World Poll’, http://www.gallup.com/consulting/worldpoll/24046/About.aspx (accessed 29 November 2011).Google Scholar
Gundlach, E. and Paldam, M. (2009), ‘A Farewell to Critical Junctures: Sorting Out Long-Run Causality of Income and Democracy’, European Journal of Political Economy, 25 (3): 340354.Google Scholar
Halman, L. C. J. M. and Draulans, V. J. R. (2006), ‘How Secular is Europe?’, British Journal of Sociology, 57 (2): 263288.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. (1960), The Constitution of Liberty, Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. (1973), Law Legislation and Liberty: Rules and Order, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Hayek, F. A. (1991), The Fatal Conceit: The Errors of Socialism, Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Heaton, P. (2006), ‘Does Religion Really Reduce Crime?’, Journal of Law & Economics, 49 (1): 147172.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heritage Foundation (2010), 2010 Index of Economic Freedom, Washington, DC: Heritage Foundation.Google Scholar
Heston, A., Summers, R., and Aten, B. (2006), Penn World Tables Mark 6.2, Center for International Comparisons of Production, Income and Prices, University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, PA.Google Scholar
Hull, B. B. and Bold, F. (1994), ‘Hell, Religion, and Cultural Change’, Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 150 (3): 447464.Google Scholar
Iannaccone, L. R., Finke, R., and Stark, R. (1997), ‘Deregulating Religion: The Economics of Church and State’,Economic Inquiry, 35 (2): 350364.Google Scholar
Iannaccone, L. R. (1998), ‘Introduction to the Economics of Religion’, Journal of Economic Literature, 36 (3): 14651496.Google Scholar
Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., and Mastruzzi, M. (2008), ‘Governance Matters VII: Aggregate and Individual Governance Indicators 1996–2007’, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 4654, Washington, DC: The World Bank.Google Scholar
Kelejian, H. H. (1971), ‘Two-Stage Least Squares and Econometric Systems Linear in Parameters but Nonlinear in the Endogenous Variables’, Journal of the American Statistical Association, 66 (334): 373374.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knack, S. (2002), ‘Social Capital and the Quality of Government: Evidence from the U.S. States’, American Journal of Political Science, 46 (4): 772785.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knack, S. and Langbein, L. (2010), ‘The Worldwide Governance Indicators and Tautology: Six, One, or None?’, Journal of Development Studies, 46 (2): 350370.Google Scholar
La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., and Vishny, R. W. (1999), ‘The Quality of Government’, Journal of Law, Economics & Organization, 15 (1): 222279.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levine, R. (2005), ‘Law, Endowments and Property Rights’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19 (3): 6188.Google Scholar
Lynn, R., Harvey, J., and Nyborg, H. (2008), ‘Average Intelligence Predicts Atheism Rates Across 137 Nations’, Intelligence, 37 (1): 1115.Google Scholar
McCleary, R. M. and Barro, R. J. (2006), ‘Religion and Economy’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20 (2): 4972.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mueller, D. C. (2009), Reason, Religion & Democracy, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
North, D. C. (1981), Structure and Change in Economic History, New York, NY: Norton.Google Scholar
North, C. M., Orman, W. H., and Gwin, C. R. (2013), ‘Religion, Corruption, and the Rule of Law’, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, forthcoming.Google Scholar
Nyborg, H. (2008), ‘The Intelligence-Religiosity Nexus: A Representative Study of White Adolescent Americans’, Intelligence, 37 (1): 8193.Google Scholar
O'Donnell, G. A. (2004), ‘Why the Rule of Law Matters’, Journal of Democracy, 15 (4): 3246.Google Scholar
Putnam, R. D. (1993), Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Putnam, R. D. and Campbell, D. E. (2010), American Grace: How Religion Divides and Unites Us, New York, NY: Simon & Schuster.Google Scholar
Rigobón, R. and Rodrik, D. (2005), ‘Rule of Law, Democracy, Openness, and Income: Estimating the Interrelationships’, Economics of Transition, 13 (3): 533564.Google Scholar
Rode, M. and Gwartney, J. D. (2012), ‘Does Democratization Facilitate Economic Liberalization?’, European Journal of Political Economy, 28 (4): 607619.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rodrik, D., Subramanian, A., and Trebbi, F. (2004), ‘Institutions Rule: The Primacy of Institutions over Geography and Integration in Economic Development’, Journal of Economic Growth, 9 (2): 131165.Google Scholar
Shariff, A. F. and Rhemtulla, M. (2012), ‘Divergent Effects of Beliefs in Heaven and Hell on National Crime Rates’, PLoS ONE, 7 (6): e39048.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Wattles, J. (1996), The Golden Rule, Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilson, R. (1997), Economics, Ethics and Religion: Jewish, Christian and Muslim Economic Thought, New York, NY: New York University Press.Google Scholar
Wisneski, D. C., Lytle, B. L., and Skitka, L. J. (2009), ‘Gut Reactions: Moral Conviction, Religiosity, and Trust in Authority’, Psychological Science, 20 (9): 10591063.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Yoo, D. and Steckel, R. H. (2010), ‘Property Rights and Financial Development: The Legacy of Japanese Colonial Institutions’, NBER Working Paper 16551, Cambridge, MA: NBER.Google Scholar
Zweynert, J. (2009), ‘Interests versus Culture in the Theory of Institutional Change?’, Journal of Institutional Economics, 5 (3): 339360.Google Scholar