Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-wq2xx Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-20T07:19:20.070Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Synthesis and reformulation of foreign policy change: Japan and East Asian financial regionalism

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  12 May 2011

Abstract

What explains major foreign policy changes? Why and when does the state change its foreign policy? Despite the importance of foreign policy change, which can (re)shape the nature of a given state's international relations vis-à-vis other states and international systems, explanations of foreign policy change have received only sporadic attention in foreign policy analysis literature. Against this backdrop, I offer in this article a new framework designed to capture both motivational and processual aspects of foreign policy change. I develop the framework by critically examining and synthesising two recent systematic explorations of foreign policy change: one framework within the tradition of rationalism (broadly defined) – David Welch's Painful Choice: A Theory of Foreign Policy Change (2005) – and the other within constructivism – Jeffrey Legro's Rethinking the World: Great Power Strategies and International Order (2006). For the motivational analysis, I link the role of crisis-defining ideas to threat perception to sharpen prospect theory. I illustrate this reformulated synthesis with an example of Japan's policy shift toward East Asian financial regionalism.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © British International Studies Association 2011

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Welch, David, Painful Choice: A Theory of Foreign Policy Change (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2005)Google Scholar .

2 Legro, Jeffrey, Rethinking the World: Great Power Strategies and International Order (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 2006)Google Scholar .

3 By ‘synthetic’ Legro means that foreign policy change derives from the dynamic interaction of national collective ideas with the demands of strategic circumstances and domestic political pressure.

4 Grimes defines East Asian financial regionalism as ‘[East Asian states'] attempts to reduce currency volatility, to create frameworks to contain financial crises, and to develop local financial markets.’ Under the auspices of ASEAN Plus Three, East Asian financial regionalism is manifested through three major initiatives: the Chiang Mai Initiative (CMI) (2000) as a framework to contain financial crises, the Asian Bond Markets Initiative (ABMI) (2002) for the development of local financial markets, and the agreement to conduct in-depth research on the feasibility of the Asian Currency Unit (ACU) (2006) for the management of currency volatility. Grimes, William, Currency and Contest in East Asia: The Great Power Politics of Financial Regionalism (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 2009)Google Scholar .

5 In this article, East Asian states refer to the members of ASEAN Plus Three (China, Japan, and Korea), which have made considerable progress in regional economic cooperation.

6 Welch, , Painful Choice, pp. 4546Google Scholar .

7 Ibid., pp. 222–3. According to Welch, Hypothesis 1 fares better as an explanation of foreign policy inertia than of foreign policy change. A major limitation of Hypothesis 2 is that its application works much better in the security domain than in the economic domain. As such, compared with Hypothesis 3, both hypotheses show rather limited empirical as well as theoretical coverage.

8 Ibid., p. 8.

9 Ibid., p. 41.

10 Ibid., p. 31.

11 Ibid., p. 47.

12 For the limitation of the bounded rationality approach to human action, see, for example, Chai, Sun-Ki, Choosing an Identity: A General Model of Preference and Belief Formation (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 2001), pp. 4345CrossRefGoogle Scholar . Chai criticises the ambiguity of the bounded rationality approach for how ‘satisfying’ [Welch's ‘acceptable’] alternatives emerge in the first place.

13 Welch himself acknowledges this as one of the major weaknesses of his theory of foreign policy change. Welch, , Painful Choice, pp. 225226Google Scholar .

14 To be fair, Welch notes this possibility of indeterminacy when he discusses the shape of the security-welfare indifference curve. Ibid., p. 25, fn. 44.

15 Lebow, Richard, A Cultural Theory of International Relations (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2008), pp. 365368, 537539CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

16 Ibid., p. 367.

17 Ibid., p. 368.

18 Ibid., p. 537.

19 Ibid., p. 366.

20 Welch, , Painful Choice, pp. 168209Google Scholar .

21 Levy, Jack, ‘Prospect Theory, Rational Choice, and International Relations’, International Studies Quarterly, 41:2 (1997), pp. 87112CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

22 Hopf, Ted, ‘The Promise of Constructivism in International Relations Theory’, International Security, 23:3 (1998), p. 193CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

23 Weldes, Jutta, ‘Constructing National Interests’, European Journal of International Relations, 2:3 (1996), p. 283CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

24 Legro, , Rethinking the World, p. 4Google Scholar .

25 Ibid., pp. 16–7. As for a theoretical account of the rise and fall of domestic foreign policy discourse in relation to external events and their associated interpretation, see, for example, Hopf, Ted, Social Construction of International Politics: Identities and Foreign Policies, Moscow, 1955 & 1999 (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 2002)Google Scholar .

26 Legro, , Rethinking the World, p. 40Google Scholar .

27 Ibid., p. 47.

28 Ibid., p. 7.

29 Ruggie, John, Constructing the World Polity: Essays on International Institutionalization (London: Routledge, 1998)CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

30 Ruggie points out that the rationalist treatment of the role of the idea (or causal beliefs) a la Goldstein and Keohane tends to employ ideas as intervening variables between interests and policy behaviours in the sense that the role of ideas is reduced to a tool used for the process of elimination or selection to better execute given interests. Ruggie, , Constructing the World Polity, pp. 1620Google Scholar . Goldstein, Judith and Keohane, Robert (eds), Ideas and Foreign Policy: Beliefs, Institutions, and Political Change (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1993)Google Scholar .

31 Wade, Robert, ‘Japan, the World Bank, and the Art of Paradigm Maintenance: The East Asian Miracle in Political Perspective’, New Left Review, 217 (1995), pp. 337Google Scholar ; Hayashi, Shigeko, Japan and East Asian Monetary Regionalism: Towards a Proactive Leadership Role? (London: Routledge, 2006)Google Scholar ; Lee, Yong Wook, The Japanese Challenge to the American Neoliberal World Order: Identity, Meaning, and Foreign Policy (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 2008)CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

32 Widmaier, Wesley, Blyth, Mark and Seabrooke, Leonard, ‘Exogenous Shocks or Endogenous Constructions? The Meanings of Wars and Crises’, International Studies Quarterly, 51:4 (2007), p. 748CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

33 On this point, Johnston makes a stronger claim that there would be no arenas of human political and social activity that are ‘idea-less’ or ‘where perceptions/worldviews do not matter’. Johnston, Alastair, Social States: China in International Institutions, 1980–2000 (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2008), p. xixCrossRefGoogle Scholar .

34 Widmaier, Blyth and Seabrooke, ‘Exogenous Shocks or Endogenous Constructions?’, p. 748.

35 Blyth, Mark, ‘Powering, Puzzling, or Persuading? The Mechanisms of Building Institutional Orders’, International Studies Quarterly, 51:4 (2007), p. 762CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

36 Bourdieu, Pierre, Outline of A Theory of Practice (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1977), pp. 159197CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

37 Johnston, Alastair, Cultural Realism: Strategic Culture and Grand Strategy in Chinese History (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1996)Google Scholar .

38 Rousseau, David, Identifying Threats and Threatening Identities: The Social Construction of Realism and Liberalism (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 2006)Google Scholar .

39 Abdelal, Rawi, National Purpose in the World Economy: Post-Soviet States in Comparative Perspective (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 2001)Google Scholar .

40 Herrera, Yoshiko, Imagined Economies: The Sources of Russian Regionalism (Ithaca: Cornell University Press), pp. 7597Google Scholar .

41 It may sound counterintuitive to say that the resulting state interest from a crisis-defining idea can be gain framing; a crisis, by definition, may imply a state of loss and thus calls for a change. As discussed earlier, however, a crisis can be perceived as such for foregone gains as well, particularly when a rival state's relative gain has security implications and/or long-term economic vitality.

42 Waltz, Kenneth, Theory of International Relations (Reading: Addison-Wesley, 1979)Google Scholar .

43 Walt, Stephen, The Origins of Alliances (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1987)Google Scholar . The other three factors that constitute the function of threat in Walt's balance of threat theory are aggregate power, offensive capability, and geographical proximity.

44 See, for example, Buzan, Barry, Wæver, Ole and Wilde, Jaap de, Security: A New Framework for Analysis (London: Lynne Rienner Publishers, 1998)Google Scholar .

45 Wendt, Alexander, Social Theory of International Politics (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1999)CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

46 Rousseau, Identifying Threats and Threatening Identities.

47 Johnston, Cultural Realism.

48 Sohn, Injoo, ‘Learning to Cooperate: China's Multilateral Approach to Asian Financial Cooperation’, China Quarterly, 194 (2008), pp. 315325CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

49 Johnston, , Social States, pp. 910Google Scholar .

50 Rousseau, , Identifying Threats and Threatening Identities, p. 213Google Scholar .

51 Alker, Hayward, Rediscoveries and Reformulations: Humanistic Methodologies for International Studies (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1996), pp. 320321CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

52 See, for example, Hayashi, Japan and East Asian Monetary Regionalism; Katada, Saori, ‘From a Supporter to a Challenger? Japan's Currency Leadership in Dollar-Dominated East Asia’, Review of International Political Economy, 15:3 (2008), pp. 399417CrossRefGoogle Scholar ; Grimes, Currency and Contest in East Asia.

53 Yasutomo, Dennis, The New Multilateralism in Japan's Foreign Policy (New York: St. Martin Press, 1995)Google Scholar ; Wade, ‘Japan, the World Bank, and the Art of Paradigm Maintenance’.

54 In his study of the evolution of ideas about the internationalisation of the yen in Japan's policy circles, Grimes reports that insulation from the negative effects of financial globalisation has been at the centre of the debate between proponents and opponents of the internationalisation of the yen since the late 1990s. Grimes, William, ‘Internationalization of the Yen and the New Politics of Monetary Insulation’, in Kirshner, Jonathan (ed.), Governing Money: Ambiguous Economics, Ubiquitous Politics (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 2003), pp. 179183Google Scholar .

55 Hatch, Walter and Yamamura, Kozo, Asia in Japan's Embrace: Building a Regional Production Alliance (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1996)CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

56 Low, Linda, ‘The East Asian Economic Grouping’, Pacific Review, 4:4 (1991), pp. 375395CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

57 Lee, Yong Wook, ‘Japan and the Asian Monetary Fund: An Identity-Intention Approach’, International Studies Quarterly, 50:2 (2006), pp. 339366CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

58 Hayashi, , Japan and East Asian Monetary Regionalism, pp. 99100Google Scholar .

59 Amyx, Jennifer, ‘Japan and the Evolution of Regional Financial Arrangements in East Asia’, in Krauss, Ellis and Pempel, T. J. (eds), Beyond Bilateralism: US-Japan Relations in the New Asia-Pacific (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 2004), pp. 198218Google Scholar .

60 As for the discussion of the CMI/AMF below, I draw on Lee, , The Japanese Challenge to the American Neoliberal World Order, pp. 173176Google Scholar .

61 Quoted from the ‘Joint Statement of East Asia Cooperation’ (28 November 1999), available at: {http://www.mofa.go.jp/region/asia-paci/asean/pmv9911/joint.html}.

62 Amyx, ‘Japan and the Evolution of Regional Financial Arrangements in East Asia’, pp. 211–2.

64 Asia Pacific Bulletin (13 May 13 2005).

65 As for a detailed analysis. See Chey, Hyung Kyu, ‘The Changing Political Dynamics of East Asian Financial Cooperation: The Chiang Mai Initiative’, Asian Survey, 49:3 (2009), pp. 450467CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

66 Ibid., p. 452.

67 Because of the space limit, the following discussion on Japan's policies toward the development of a regional financial market and the management of currency volatility by developing the Asian Common Currency is very brief. As for detailed accounts, see Hayashi, Japan and East Asian Monetary Regionalism, chap. 5; Katada, ‘From a Supporter to a Challenger?’; Grimes, Currency and Contest in East Asia, chaps 4 and 5.

68 Rowley 2003, in Katada, Saori, ‘Politics That Constrains: The Logic of Fragmented Regionalism in East Asia’, EAI Fellow Program Working Paper #21 (Seoul: East Asian Institute, 2009)Google Scholar .

69 As noted earlier, Kawaii and Kuroda, two former MOF officials, were instrumental in the development of the CMI.

70 Wesley, Michael, ‘The Asian Crisis and the Adequacy of Regional Institutions’, Contemporary Southeast Asia, 21:1 (1999), pp. 5473CrossRefGoogle Scholar ; Dierter, Heribert and Higgott, Richard, ‘Exploring Alternative Theories of Economic Regionalism: From Trade to Finance in Asian Co-operation?’, Review of International Political Economy, 10:3 (2003), pp. 430454CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

71 Hughes, Christopher, ‘Japanese Policy and the East Asian Currency Crisis: Abject Defeat or Quiet Victory?’, Review of International Political Economy, 7:2 (2000), pp. 219253CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

72 Ravenhill, John, ‘The New Bilateralism in the Asia Pacific’, Third World Quarterly, 24:2 (2003), pp. 299317CrossRefGoogle Scholar ; Grimes, Currency and Contest in East Asia.

73 Katada, Saori, Banking on Stability: Japan and Cross-Pacific Dynamics of International Financial Crisis Management (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 2001)CrossRefGoogle Scholar ; Hayashi, Japan and East Asian Monetary Regionalism; Lee, The Japanese Challenge to the American Neoliberal World Order.

74 Grimes, William, ‘East Asian Financial Regionalism in Support of the Global Financial Architecture? The Political Economy of Regional Nesting’, Journal of East Asian Studies, 6:3 (2006), pp. 353380CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

75 Interview with Sakakibara, New Strait Times (31 January 2000).

76 Ravenhill, John, ‘A Three Bloc World? The New Asian Regionalism’, International Relations of the Asia-Pacific, 2:2 (2002), p. 175CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

77 Higgott, Richard, ‘The Asian Economic Crisis: A Study in the Politics of Resentment’, New Political Economy, 3:3 (1998), pp. 333356CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

78 Bergstein, C. F., ‘Towards a Tripartite World’, The Economist (15 July 2000)Google Scholar .

79 Interview with an official of the Ministry of Finance, Washington DC (10 June 2006).

80 Chey, ‘The Changing Political Dynamics of East Asian Financial Cooperation’, pp. 460–1.

81 Eisuke Sakakibara, ‘The Asian Monetary Fund: Where Do We Go from Here?’ Paper presented at ‘International Conference on Globalization’, Kuala Lumpur (26 February 2001), p. 7.

82 Hayashi, , Japan and East Asian Monetary Regionalism, p. 109Google Scholar .

83 Ibid., p. 119.

84 Noland, Marcus, ‘US Economic Policy toward Asia’, Economics Series #109 (Washington DC: East-West Centre), p. 13Google Scholar .

85 Hamanaka, Shintaro, Asian Regionalism and Japan: The Politics of Membership in Regional Diplomatic, Financial, and Trade Groups (London: Routledge, 2009), pp. 117119Google Scholar .

86 Pascha 2003 in Chey, ‘The Changing Political Dynamics of East Asian Financial Cooperation’, p. 461.

87 Grimes, ‘East Asian Financial Regionalism in Support of the Global Financial Architecture?’, p. 357.

88 Ministry of Finance, ‘Resource Mobilization Plan for Asia: The Second Stage of the New Miyazawa Initiative’ {http://www.mof.go.jp/english/if/e1b068.htm}.

90 Grimes, Currency and Contest in East Asia.

91 Interview with an official of the Ministry of Finance, Washington DC (10 June 2006).

92 Lee, , The Japanese Challenge to the American Neoliberal World Order, p. 161Google Scholar . This does not suggest that there was serious policy competition within the MOF. The pro-IMF faction constituted a small minority in the entire process of the MOF's decision to ‘go regional’. See, for example, Green, Michael, Japan's Reluctant Realism: Foreign Policy Challenges in an Era of Uncertain Power (New York: Palgrave, 2001), pp. 239257CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

93 Green, , Japan's Reluctant Realism, pp. 256257Google Scholar .

94 Hayashi, , Japan and East Asian Monetary Regionalism, pp. 111112Google Scholar .

95 The Blue Book is the annual official account of Japan's foreign policy complied by the MOFA.

96 Hayashi, , Japan and East Asian Monetary Regionalism, pp. 111, 118Google Scholar .

97 Katada, Saori and Solis, Mireya, ‘Domestic Sources of Japanese Policy Activism: Low Avoidance and Demand Coherence’, International Relations of the Asia-Pacific, 10:1 (2010), pp. 129157CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

98 Lee, , The Japanese Challenge to the American Neoliberal World Order, p. 162Google Scholar .

99 Hayashi, , Japan and East Asian Monetary Regionalism, pp. 110111Google Scholar .

100 This does not mean that Japan's private sector took the lead in developing Japan's policies toward financial regionalism. As Katada and Solis report in detail, Japan's policies have been largely determined by the MOF's position with a top-down quality. According to them, Japan's private sector has had a fairly limited access to the MOF's policymaking in regional financial cooperation. Katada and Solis, ‘Domestic Sources of Japanese Policy Activism’.

101 Frieden, Jeffrey, ‘Invested Interests: The Politics of National Economic Policies in a World of Global Finance’, International Organization, 45:4 (1991), pp. 425451CrossRefGoogle Scholar .

102 Kirshner, Jonathan, ‘States, Markets, and Great Power Relations in the Pacific: Some Realist Expectations’, in Ikenberry, John and Mastanduno, Michael (eds), International Theory and the Asia-Pacific (New York: Columbia University Press, 2003), pp. 273298Google Scholar .

103 Katada and Solis, ‘Domestic Sources of Japanese Policy Activism’.

104 Abdelal, Rawi, Blyth, Mark, and Parson, Craig, ‘Reconstructing IPE: Some Conclusions Drawn from a Crisis’, in Abdelal, Rawi, Blyth, Mark, and Parson, Craig (eds), Constructing the International Economy (Ithaca: Cornell University Press), p. 234Google Scholar .