Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-xtgtn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-24T15:40:32.049Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Fading Friendships: Alliances, Affinities and the Activation of International Identities

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  03 July 2012

Abstract

In international politics ‘friends’ co-ally. But friendship is relational and contextual. Countries are more likely to act on particular common interests if few other actors share that identity. In contrast, new cleavages are likely to emerge as an identity becomes ubiquitous. The tendency for states to form alliances based on certain affinities is thus best thought of as a variable, rather than as a constant. For example, in systems where democracies are scarce, democracies eagerly co-ally. As democracy becomes common, however, incentives binding democratic allies together weaken compared to other definitions of mutual interest. This argument, and the evidence we provide, suggest that the salience of identities as cues to affinity and difference vary with the distribution of types in the system.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2012

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

*

Department of Political Science, University of California San Diego (email: egartzke@ucsd.edu); and Department of Political Science, University of Pennsylvania (email: weisiger@sas.upenn.edu), respectively. The authors thank Brett Benson, Kristian Gleditsch and anonymous reviewers for helpful comments and suggestions, and Mark Crescenzi and Andrew Enterline for use of their data on dyadic threats. An appendix containing additional information is available online at: http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0007123412000208.

References

1 Bruce Bueno de Mesquita, The War Trap (New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press)Google Scholar

Fearon, James D., ‘Signaling Foreign Policy Interests: Tying Hands versus Sinking Costs’, Journal of Conflict Resolution, 41 (1997), 6890 Google Scholar

Spence, Michael, ‘Job Market Signaling’, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 87 (1973), 355374 CrossRefGoogle Scholar

2 Smith, Alastair, ‘Alliance Formation and War’, International Studies Quarterly, 39 (1995), 405425 CrossRefGoogle Scholar

3 Siverson, Randolph M. and Emmons, Juliann, ‘Birds of a Feather: Democratic Political Systems and Alliance Choices in the Twentieth Century’, Journal of Conflict Resolution, 35 (1991), 285306 CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Simon, Michael W. and Gartzke, Erik, ‘Political System Similarity and the Choice of Allies: Do Democracies Flock Together or Do Opposites Attract?’ Journal of Conflict Resolution, 40 (1996), 617635 Google Scholar

4 Lai, Brian and Reiter, Dan, ‘Democracy, Political Similarity, and International Alliances, 1816–2002’, Journal of Conflict Resolution, 44 (2000), 203227 Google Scholar

5 Alliances are arguably more amenable to change than arms spending (given other demands on national budgets).

6 The argument applies in principle to treaties and international institutions generally. We focus on alliances as an adequate test of the argument and because pooling different types of institutions is problematic for various reasons.

7 Glaser, Charles L., ‘Realists as Optimists: Cooperation as Self-Help’, International Security, 19 (1994), 5090 CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Stephen Van Evera, ‘Offense, Defense, and the Causes of War’, International Security, 22 (1998), 543 Google Scholar

Taliaferro, Jeffrey W., ‘Security Seeking under Anarchy: Defensive Realism Revisited’, International Security, 25 (2000), 128161 Google Scholar

8 Waltz, Kenneth N., Man, the State, and War (New York: Columbia University Press, 1959)Google Scholar

Waltz, Kenneth N., Theory of International Politics (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1979)Google Scholar

9 Gilpin, Robert, War and Change in World Politics (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1981)Google Scholar

Thompson, William R., On Global War: Historical-Structural Approaches to World Politics (Columbia: University of South Carolina Press, 1988)Google Scholar

Snidal, Duncan, ‘The Limits of Hegemonic Stability Theory’, International Organization, 39 (1985), 579614 CrossRefGoogle Scholar

10 Mearsheimer, John J., The Tragedy of Great Power Politics (New York: W.W. Norton, 2001)Google Scholar

Schweller, Randall L., ‘Bandwagoning for Profit: Bringing the Revisionist State Back In’, International Security, 19 (1994), 72107 Google Scholar

Schweller, Randall L., ‘Neorealism's Status-Quo Bias: What Security Dilemma?’ Security Studies, 5 (1996), 90121 Google Scholar

Schweller, Randall L., Deadly Imbalances: Tripolarity and Hitler's Strategy of World Conquest (New York: Columbia University Press, 1998)Google Scholar

11 Grieco, Joseph M., Cooperation among Nations: Europe, America, and Non-Tariff Barriers to Trade (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1990)CrossRefGoogle Scholar

12 Alliances can be made where all members receive exactly the same (proportionate) increase (decrease) in security.

13 Niou, Emerson S., Ordeshook, Peter and Rose, Gregory, The Balance of Power: Stability in International Systems (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1989)Google Scholar

14 Powell, Robert, ‘Absolute and Relative Gains in International Relations Theory’, American Political Science Review, 85 (1991), 13031320 Google Scholar

Snidal, Duncan, ‘Relative Gains and the Pattern of International Cooperation’, American Political Science Review, 85 (1991), 701726 Google Scholar

15 Indeed, the decision to arm or ally must introduce domestic politics into international affairs, countering Waltz's conviction that international imperatives dictate foreign policy, and that domestic politics can safely be ignored.

16 Sorokin, Gerald L., ‘Alliance Formation and General Deterrence: A Game-Theoretic Model and the Case of Israel’, Journal of Conflict Resolution, 38 (1994), 298325 Google Scholar

Sorokin, Gerald L., ‘Arms, Alliances, and Security Tradeoffs in Enduring Rivalries’, International Studies Quarterly, 38 (1994), 421446 Google Scholar

17 Olson, Mancur and Zeckhauser, Richard, ‘An Economic Theory of Alliances’, Review of Economics and Statistics, 48 (1966), 266279 Google Scholar

Sandler, Todd, ‘The Economic Theory of Alliances: A Survey’, Journal of Conflict Resolution, 37 (1993), 446483 Google Scholar

Sandler, Todd and Hartley, Keith, The Economics of Defense (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1995)Google Scholar

18 Altfeld, Michael F., ‘The Decision to Ally: A Theory and Test’, Western Political Quarterly, 37 (1984), 523544 Google Scholar

Morrow, James D., ‘Alliances and Asymmetry: An Alternative to the Capability Aggregation Model of Alliances’, American Journal of Political Science, 35 (1991), 904933 Google Scholar

19 Signorino, Curtis S. and Ritter, Jeffrey M., ‘Tau-b or Not Tau-b: Measuring the Similarity of Foreign Policy Positions’, International Studies Quarterly, 43 (2001), 115144 CrossRefGoogle Scholar

20 Morrow, James D., ‘Alliances, Credibility, and Peacetime Costs’, Journal of Conflict Resolution, 38 (1994), 270294 Google Scholar

21 Christensen, Thomas J. and Snyder, Jack, ‘Chain Gangs and Passed Bucks: Predicting Alliance Patterns in Multipolarity’, International Organization, 44 (1990), 137168 Google Scholar

Bearce, David H., Flanagan, Kristen M. and Floros, Katherine M., ‘Alliances, Internal Information, and Military Conflict among Member States’, International Organization 60 (2006), 595–625CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Gartzke, Erik, ‘Alliances, Reputation, and International Politics’, University of California, San Diego, typescript, 2010Google Scholar

22 Gowa, Joanne and Mansfield, Edward D., ‘Power Politics and International Trade’, American Political Science Review, 87 (1993), 408420 Google Scholar

Gowa, Joanne and Mansfield, Edward D., ‘Alliances, Imperfect Markets, and Major Power Trade’, International Organization, 58 (2004), 775805 Google Scholar

Mansfield, Edward D. and Bronson, Rachel, ‘Alliances, Preferential Trading Agreements, and International Trade’, American Political Science Review, 91 (1997), 94107 CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Morrow, James D., Siverson, Randolph M. and Tabares, Tressa E., ‘The Political Determinants of International Trade: The Major Powers, 1907–90’, American Political Science Review, 92 (1998), 649661 Google Scholar

Fordham, Benjamin O., ‘Trade and Asymmetric Alliances’, Journal of Peace Research, 47 (2010), 685696 Google Scholar

23 Huntington, Samuel P., The Clash of Civilizations and the Remaking of World Order (New York: Simon and Schuster, 1996)Google Scholar

Mearsheimer, John J. and Walt, Stephen M., ‘The Israel Lobby and U.S. Policy’, Middle East Policy 13 (2006), 29–87Google Scholar

Paul, David M. and Paul, Rachel Anderson, Ethnic Lobbies and US Foreign Policy (Boulder, Colo.: Lynne Rienner, 2009)Google Scholar

Smith, Tony, Foreign Attachments: The Power of Ethnic Groups in Making American Foreign Policy (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 2000)Google Scholar

24 Bueno de Mesquita, The War Trap; Smith, ‘Alliance Formation and War’.

25 Walt, Stephen M., The Origins of Alliances (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1987)Google Scholar

26 Sorokin, ‘Alliance Formation and General Deterrence’; Sorokin, ‘Arms, Alliances, and Security Tradeoffs in Enduring Rivalries’.

27 Siverson, Randolph M. and Starr, Harvey, ‘Regime Change and the Restructuring of Alliances’, American Journal of Political Science, 38 (1994), 145161 Google Scholar

28 Siverson and Emmons, ‘Birds of a Feather’.

29 Anessa L. Kimball, ‘Alliance Formation and Conflict Initiation: The Missing Link’, Journal of Peace Research, 43 (2006), 371–189Google Scholar

30 William R. Thompson, ‘Systemic Leadership and the Democratic Peace’, Indiana University, typescript, 1995.

31 Simon and Gartzke, ‘Political System Similarity and the Choice of Allies’.

32 Lai and Reiter, ‘Democracy, Political Similarity, and International Alliances’.

33 Bennett, D. Scott, ‘Testing Alternative Models of Alliance Duration, 1816–1984’, American Journal of Political Science, 41 (1997), 846878 Google Scholar

Gaubatz, Kurt Taylor, ‘Democratic States and Commitment in International Relations’, International Organization, 50 (1996), 109139 Google Scholar

Reed, William, ‘Alliance Duration and Democracy: An Extension and Cross-Validation of ‘‘Democratic States and Commitment in International Relations’’ ’, American Journal of Political Science, 41 (1997), 10721078 Google Scholar

34 Reiter, Dan and Stam, Allan C., Democracies at War (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 2002)Google Scholar

Choi, Ajin, ‘Democratic Synergy and Victory in War, 1816–1992’, International Studies Quarterly, 48 (2004), 663682 Google Scholar

35 Leeds, Brett Ashley, ‘Alliance Reliability in Times of War: Explaining State Decisions to Violate Treaties’, International Organization, 57 (2003), 801827 Google Scholar

Gartzke, Erik and Gleditsch, Kristian S., ‘Why Democracies May Actually Be Less Reliable Allies’, American Journal of Political Science, 48 (2004), 775795 Google Scholar

Leeds, Brett Ashley, Mattes, Michaela and Vogel, Jeremy S., ‘Interests, Institutions, and the Reliability of International Commitments’, American Journal of Political Science, 53 (2009), 461476 Google Scholar

36 Kupchan, Charles A. and Kupchan, Clifford A., ‘The Promise of Collective Security’, International Security, 20 (1995), 5261 CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Risse-Kappen, Thomas, ‘Collective Identity in a Democratic Community: The Case of NATO’, in Peter Katzenstein, ed., The Culture of National Security: Norms and Identity in World Politics (New York: Columbia University Press, 1996), pp. 357399 Google Scholar

Risse-Kappen, Thomas, Cooperation Among Democracies: The European Influence on U.S. Foreign Policy (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1997)Google Scholar

Wendt, Alexander, Social Theory of International Politics (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1999)Google Scholar

Betts, Richard K., ‘Systems for Peace or Causes of War? Collective Security, Arms Control, and the New Empire’, International Security, 17 (1992), 543 Google Scholar

37 Kadera, Kelly M., Crescenzi, Marc J.C. and Shannon, Megan L., ‘Democratic Survival, Peace, and War in the International System’, American Journal of Political Science, 47 (2003), 234247 Google Scholar

38 We directly examine the dynamic relationship between regime type and alliance status in the empirical section.

39 Gleditsch, Kristian, All International Politics Is Local: The Diffusion of Conflict, Integration, and Democratization (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 2002)Google Scholar

40 Mearsheimer, John J., ‘Back to the Future: Instability in Europe after the Cold War’, International Security, 15 (1990), 556 Google Scholar

Waltz, Kenneth N., ‘The Emerging Structure of International Politics’, International Security, 18 (1993), 7576 Google Scholar

41 Hopf, Ted, Social Construction of International Politics: Identities and Foreign Policies, Moscow, 1955 and 1999 (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 2002)Google Scholar

42 Zakaria, Fareed, ‘The Rise of Illiberal Democracy’, Foreign Affairs, 76 (1997), 2243 Google Scholar

43 ‘Simply because it won the votes of a desperate people is no reason to grant even the slightest scrap of legitimacy – or the first aid dollar – to Hamas’ (Mortimer B. Zuckerman, U.S. News and World Report, 13 February 2006, p. 63).

44 The model was constructed using NetLogo. Additional details and the code are available from the authors.

45 The model assumes that interactions among allied actors produce policy outcomes at the alliance's effective ideal point. In two-member alliances, this point is identical to the policy outcome that would have arisen in the absence of an alliance. In larger alliances, however, the outcome with the alliance differs from the outcome without it, providing an additional potential basis to accept or reject an alliance proposal.

46 An appendix detailing the pseudocode, as well as other details of the model, is available from the authors.

47 Cederman, Lars-Erik, ‘Modeling the Size of Wars: From Billiard Balls to Sandpiles’, American Political Science Review, 97 (2003), 135150 CrossRefGoogle Scholar

48 This approach is taken for simplicity, as it ensures closed alliances and thus avoids questions about how to determine policy outcomes in complex situations, as with interactions between unallied actors who share an ally. We have also examined a number of alternative approaches, each of which yields substantively identical results.

49 Note that accepting an alliance does not preclude an actor from subsequently taking a turn as alliance proposer, although any alliance that that actor proposes must be approved by their ally before it can come into effect.

50 Fearon, James D., ‘Rationalist Explanations for War’, International Organization, 49 (1995), 379414 Google Scholar

51 For actors with no alliance partners, k is fixed to 1, as alliance inefficiencies obviously are not a pertinent factor.

52 Because interactions with allies produce outcomes at the alliance effective ideal point, i gains the same utility from every interaction with an ally. We can thus simply multiply that utility by the number of allies, rather than having to sum over each ally.

53 This point illustrates the tensions inherent in the use of an agent-based model. Relative to a game-theoretic model, actors in our model are not particularly forward-looking. For example, they do not consider the possibility that agreeing to an alliance proposal now might allow the new alliance partner to veto a more attractive alliance proposal at a later date. We would only be able to capture this sort of foresight by dramatically limiting the number of actors in the resulting game-theoretic model, a much less appealing compromise given the objectives of this study.

54 A detailed set of representative results at different parameter values appears in the online appendix.

55 For simplicity, the model contains democracies and autocracies, but does not include ‘anocracies’. The empirical world includes states that are neither fully democratic nor autocratic, adding to the challenge of connecting theory with evidence. As we will see, however, this distinction does not appear to critically affect tests of the theory.

56 Lai and Reiter, ‘Democracy, Political Similarity, and International Alliances’.

57 Plotting only jointly democratic alliance dyads reveals a similar pattern of rising propensity to ally over time (available from the authors). Our interest here is in the relative shift in democratic preference for democratic partners.

58 Neal Beck, Jonathan Katz and Richard Tucker, ‘Taking Time Seriously: Time-Series-Cross-Section Analysis with a Binary Dependent Variable’, American Journal of Political Science, 42 (1998), 12601288 Google Scholar

59 D. Scott Bennett and Scott E. Tarry, ‘Self-Perpetuation or Rational Choices? A Model of Rationality and Hysteresis in International Alliances’ (paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association, Chicago, 1996).

60 Carter, David B. and Signorino, Curtis, ‘Back to the Future: Modeling Time Dependence in Binary Data’, Political Analysis, 18 (2010), 271292 Google Scholar

61 Bennett, D. Scott and Stam, Allan C., ‘EUGene: A Conceptual Manual’, International Interactions, 26 (2000), 179204 Google Scholar

62 Achen, Christopher H., ‘Let's Put Garbage-Can Regressions and Garbage-Can Probits Where They Belong’, Conflict Management and Peace Science, 22 (2005), 327339 Google Scholar

Clarke, Kevin A., ‘The Phantom Menace: Omitted Variable Bias in Econometric Research’, Conflict Management and Peace Science, 22 (2005), 341352 Google Scholar

Ray, James Lee, ‘Constructing Multivariate Analyses (of Dangerous Dyads)’, Conflict Management and Peace Science, 22 (2005), 277292 Google Scholar

63 C.f. John R. Oneal and Bruce Russett, ‘The Classical Liberals Were Right: Democracy, Interdependence, and Conflict, 1950–1985’, International Studies Quarterly, 41 (1997), 267293 Google Scholar

Oneal, John R., Russett, Bruce and Berbaum, Michael L., ‘Causes of Peace: Democracy, Interdependence, and International Organizations’, International Studies Quarterly, 47 (2003), 371393 Google Scholar

64 Small, Melvin and Singer, J. David, ‘Formal Alliances, 1816–1965: An Extension of the Basic Data’, in J. David Singer and Paul F. Diehl, eds, Measuring the Correlates of War (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1990), pp. 159190 Google Scholar

Gibler, Douglas and Sarkees, Meredith Reid, ‘Measuring Alliances: The Correlates of War Formal International Alliance Dataset, 1816–2000’, Journal of Peace Research, 41 (2004), 211222 Google Scholar

Leeds, Brett Ashley, Long, Andrew G. and Mitchell, Sara McLaughlin, ‘Reevaluating Alliance Reliability: Specific Threats, Specific Promises’, Journal of Conflict Resolution, 44 (2000), 686699 Google Scholar

65 Jaggers, Keith and Gurr, Ted R., ‘Transitions to Democracy: Tracking Democracy's ‘‘Third Wave’’ with the Polity III Data’, Journal of Peace Research, 32 (1995), 469482 CrossRefGoogle Scholar

66 Mitchell, Sara McLaughlin, Gates, Scott and Hegre, Håvard, ‘Evolution in Democracy-War Dynamics’, Journal of Conflict Resolution, 43 (1999), 771792 Google Scholar

Cederman, Lars-Erik, ‘Modeling the Democratic Peace as a Kantian Selection Process’, Journal of Conflict Resolution, 45 (2001), 470502 CrossRefGoogle Scholar

67 Lars-Erik Cederman and Kristian Gleditsch, ‘Conquest and Regime Change: An Evolutionary Model of the Spread of Democracy and Peace’, International Studies Quarterly, 48 (2004), 603629 Google Scholar

68 Hensel, Paul R., ‘Territory: Theory and Evidence on Geography and Conflict’, in John A. Vasquez, ed., What Do We Know about War? (New York: Rowman & Littlefield, 2000), pp. 5784 Google Scholar

Senese, Paul, ‘Territory, Contiguity, and International Conflict: Assessing a New Joint Explanation’, American Journal of Political Science, 49 (2005), 769779 Google Scholar

69 Crescenzi, Mark J.C. and Enterline, Andrew J., ‘Time Remembered: A Dynamic Model of Interstate Interaction’, International Studies Quarterly, 45 (2001), 409–431CrossRefGoogle Scholar

70 This variable is an admittedly imperfect measure of common threat. An alternative approach would be to use the number of MIDs against similar actors, but this raises difficult questions about an appropriate time lag between disputes in different dyads consistent with the existence of a common threat. We leave this issue for future research.

71 The substitution of democracies for autocracies is not one-for-one, as many states fall into the middle (‘anocracy’) category. The point is not deductive, but simply an empirical one that democracies are ‘crowding out’ autocracies.

72 This problem may occur in other contexts as well. It is common to extend datasets in international relations temporally. Any differences between older analyses using shorter time-series and more recent studies including this new data could either be the result of more or better data or temporal changes in underlying causal relationships.

Supplementary material: PDF

Gartzke Supplementary Material

Appendix

Download Gartzke Supplementary Material(PDF)
PDF 129.4 KB
Supplementary material: File

Gartzke Supplementary Material

Gartzke Supplementary Material

Download Gartzke Supplementary Material(File)
File 12.1 KB