Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-m8qmq Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-18T09:42:10.032Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Why Do Some Countries Get Better WTO Accession Terms Than Others?

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  07 October 2011

Krzysztof J. Pelc
Affiliation:
McGill University, Montreal. E-mail: kj.pelc@mcgill.ca
Get access

Abstract

The process by which countries accede to the World Trade Organization (WTO) has become the subject of considerable debate. This article takes a closer look at what determines the concessions the institution requires of an entrant. In other words, who gets a good deal, and who does not? I argue that given the institutional design of accession proceedings and the resulting suspension of reciprocity, accession terms are driven by the domestic export interests of existing members. As a result, relatively greater liberalization will be imposed on those entrants that have more valuable market access to offer upon accession, something that appears to be in opposition to expectations during multilateral trade rounds, where market access functions as a bargaining chit. The empirical evidence supports these assertions. Looking at eighteen recent entrants at the six-digit product level, I find that controlling for a host of country-specific variables, as well as the applied protection rates on a given product prior to accession, the more a country has to offer, the more it is required to give. Moreover, I show how more democratic countries, in spite of their greater overall depth of integration, exhibit greater resistance to adjustment in key industries than do nondemocracies. Finally, I demonstrate that wealth exhibits a curvilinear effect. On the one hand, institutionalized norms lead members to exercise observable restraint vis-à-vis the poorest countries. On the other hand, the richest countries have the greatest bargaining expertise, and thus obtain better terms. The outcome, as I show using a semi-parametric analysis, is that middle-income countries end up with the most stringent terms, and have to make the greatest relative adjustments to their trade regimes.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The IO Foundation 2011

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Adhikari, Ramesh, and Yang, Yongzheng. 2002. What Will WTO Membership Mean for China and Its Trading Partners? Finance and Development 39 (3). Available at ⟨http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/2002/09/adhikari.htm⟩. Accessed 3 May 2011.Google Scholar
Bagwell, Kyle, and Staiger, Robert W.. 1999. An Economic Theory of GATT. American Economic Review 89 (1):215–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bown, Chad P., and Tovar, Patricia. 2009. Trade Liberalization, Antidumping, and Safeguards: Evidence from India's Tariff Reform. Unpublished manuscript, Brandeis University, Waltham, Mass.Google Scholar
Brambor, Thomas, Clark, William R., and Golder, Matt. 2006. Understanding Interaction Models: Improving Empirical Analyses. Political Analysis 14 (1):6382.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Busch, Marc L. 2007. Overlapping Institutions, Forum Shopping, and Dispute Settlement in International Trade. International Organization 61 (4):735–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Busch, Marc L., and Reinhardt, Eric. 2000. Geography, International Trade, and Political Mobilization in U.S. Industries. American Journal of Political Science 44 (4):703–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Busch, Marc L., Reinhardt, Eric, and Shaffer, Gregory. 2009. Does Legal Capacity Matter? A Survey of WTO Members. World Trade Review 8 (4):559–77.Google Scholar
Cattaneo, Olivier, and Braga, Carlos A. Primo. 2009. Everything You Always Wanted to Know About WTO Accession (but Were Afraid to Ask). World Bank Policy Research Paper 5116. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clark, Ian. 2005. Legitimacy in International Society. Oxford, England: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Copelovitch, Mark S., and Ohls, David. Forthcoming. Trade, Institutions, and the Timing of GATT/WTO Accession in Postcolonial States. The Review of International Organizations.Google Scholar
Destler, I. M., and Odell, John S.. 1987. Anti-Protection: Changing Forces in United States Trade Politics. Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Economics.Google Scholar
Downs, George W., Rocke, David M., and Barsoom, Peter N.. 1996. Is the Good News About Compliance Good News About Cooperation? International Organization 50 (3):379406.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Downs, George W., Rocke, David M., and Barsoom, Peter N.. 1998. Managing the Evolution of Multilateralism. International Organization 52 (2):397419.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Drabek, Zdenek, and Bacchetta, Marc. 2004. Tracing the Effects of WTO Accession on Policy-Making in Sovereign States: Preliminary Lessons from the Recent Experience of Transition Countries. World Economy 27 (7):1083–125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Evenett, Simon J., and Braga, Carlos A. Primo. 2006. WTO Accession: Moving the Goalposts? In Trade, Doha, and Development: A Window into the Issues, edited by Newfarmer, Richard S., 227–41. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.Google Scholar
Francois, Joseph F., and Martin, Will. 2004. Commercial Policy Variability, Bindings, and Market Access. European Economic Review 48 (3):665–79.Google Scholar
Gay, Daniel. 2005. Vanuatu's Suspended Accession Bid: Second Thoughts? In Managing the Challenges of WTO Participation: 45 Case Studies, edited by Gallagher, Peter, Low, Patrick, and Stoler, Andrew L., 590606. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Ghosh, Arunabha. 2010. Making Climate Look Like Trade? Questions on Incentives, Flexibility, and Credibility. CPR Policy Brief. New Delhi, India: Centre for Policy Research.Google Scholar
Goldstein, Judith L., Rivers, Douglas, and Tomz, Michael. 2007. Institutions in International Relations: Understanding the Effects of the GATT and the WTO on World Trade. International Organization 61 (1):3767.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gowa, Joanne S. 2010. Alliances, Market Power, and Postwar Trade: Explaining the GATT/WTO. World Trade Review 9 (3):487504.Google Scholar
Gowa, Joanne S., and Kim, Soo Yeon. 2005. An Exclusive Country Club: The Effects of the GATT on Trade, 1950–94. World Politics 57 (4):453–78.Google Scholar
Grynberg, Roman, and Joy, Roy Mickey. 2000. The Accession of Vanuatu to the WTO: Lessons for the Multilateral Trading System. Journal of World Trade 34 (6):159–73.Google Scholar
Ikenberry, G. John. 2001. After Victory: Institutions, Strategic Restraint, and the Rebuilding of Order After Major Wars. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ingco, Merlinda. 1998. Agricultural Protection. In Global Trade Assistance and Protection: The GTAP 3 Data Base, edited by McDougall, Robert A., Elbehri, Aziz, and Truong, Truong P.. West Lafayette, Ind.: Center for Global Trade Analysis, Purdue University. Available at ⟨https://www.gtap.agecon.purdue.edu/resources/download/563.pdf⟩. Accessed 4 May 2011.Google Scholar
Keohane, Robert O. 1984. After Hegemony: Cooperation and Discord in the World Political Economy. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
King, Gary, Tomz, Michael, and Wittenberg, Jason. 2000. Making the Most of Statistical Analyses: Improving Interpretation and Presentation. American Journal of Political Science 44 (2):347–61.Google Scholar
Maggi, Giovanni, and Rodríguez-Clare, Andrés. 1998. The Value of Trade Agreements in the Presence of Political Pressures. Journal of Political Economy 106 (3):574601.Google Scholar
Mansfield, Edward D., Milner, Helen V., and Rosendorff, B. Peter. 2002. Why Democracies Cooperate More: Electoral Control and International Trade Agreements. International Organization 56 (3):477513.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mansfield, Edward D., and Reinhardt, Eric. 2008. International Institutions and the Volatility of International Trade. International Organization 62 (4):621–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marshall, Monty G., Gurr, Ted Robert, and Jaggers, Keith. 2010. Polity IV Project: Political Regime Characteristics and Transitions, 1800–2009. Dataset Users' Manual. Center for Systemic Peace. Available at ⟨http://www.systemicpeace.org/inscr/p4manualv2009.pdf⟩. Accessed 11 May 2011.Google Scholar
Martin, Lisa L., and Simmons, Beth A.. 1998. Theories and Empirical Studies of International Institutions. International Organization 52 (4):729–57.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McGillivray, Fiona. 2004. Privileging Industry: The Comparative Politics of Trade and Industrial Policy. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Michalopoulos, Constantine. 1999. Trade Policy and Market Access Issues for Developing Countries: Implications for the Millennium Round. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 2214. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.Google Scholar
Milner, Helen V. 1997. Interests, Institutions, and Information: Domestic Politics and International Relations. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Olson, Mancur. 1971. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Rev. ed. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Özden, Çaglar, and Reinhardt, Eric. 2005. The Perversity of Preferences: GSP and Developing Country Trade Policies, 1976–2000. Journal of Development Economics 78 (1):121.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pelc, Krzysztof J. 2011. How States Ration Flexibility: Tariffs, Remedies, and Exchange Rates as Policy Substitutes. World Politics 63 (4).Google Scholar
Pelc, Krzysztof J. Forthcoming. The Cost of Wiggle-Room: Looking at the Welfare Effects of Flexibility in Tariff Rates at the WTO. International Studies Quarterly.Google Scholar
Putnam, Robert D. 1988. Diplomacy and Domestic Politics: The Logic of Two-Level Games. International Organization 42 (3):427–60.Google Scholar
Rose, Andrew K. 2004. Do We Really Know that the WTO Increases Trade? American Economic Review 94 (1):98114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Royston, Patrick, and Ambler, Gareth. 2002. GAM: Stata Module for Generalised Additive Models. Statistical Software Component S428701. Chestnut Hill, Mass.: Department of Economics, Boston College. Available at ⟨http://ideas.repec.org/c/boc/bocode/s428701.html⟩. Accessed 5 May 2011.Google Scholar
Schelling, Thomas C. 1956. An Essay on Bargaining. American Economic Review 46 (3):281306.Google Scholar
Simmons, Beth A. 2000. International Law and State Behavior: Commitment and Compliance in International Monetary Affairs. American Political Science Review 94 (4):819–35.Google Scholar
Smith, James McCall. 2006. Compliance Bargaining in the WTO: Ecuador and the Bananas Dispute. In Negotiating Trade: Developing Countries in the WTO and NAFTA, edited by Odell, John S., 257–88. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Staiger, Robert W., and Tabellini, Guido. 1987. Discretionary Trade Policy and Excessive Protection. American Economic Review 77 (5):823–37.Google Scholar
Steinberg, Richard H. 2002. In the Shadow of Law or Power? Consensus-Based Bargaining and Outcomes in the GATT/WTO. International Organization 56 (2):339–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stiglitz, Joseph E., and Charlton, Andrew. 2005. Fair Trade for All: How Trade Can Promote Development. Oxford, England: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Subramanian, Arvind, and Wei, Shang-Jin. 2007. The WTO Promotes Trade, Strongly but Unevenly. Journal of International Economics 72 (1):151–75.Google Scholar
Von Stein, Jana. 2005. Do Treaties Constrain or Screen? Selection Bias and Treaty Compliance. American Political Science Review 99 (4):611–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
World Bank. 2010. World Development Indicators 2010. Washington, D.C.: World Bank. Available at ⟨http://data.worldbank.org/sites/default/files/wdi-final.pdf⟩. Accessed 11 May 2011.Google Scholar