Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-wq2xx Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-18T04:51:06.468Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Legislative Voting in the Canadian Parliament

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  29 June 2011

Jean-François Godbout*
Affiliation:
Université de Montréal
Bjørn Høyland*
Affiliation:
University of Oslo
*
Jean-François Godbout, Département de science politique, Université de Montréal, C.P. 6128, succursale Centre-ville, Montréal QC H3C 3J7; jean-francois.godbout@umontreal.ca
Bjørn Høyland, Department of Political Science, University of Oslo, PO Box 1097 Blindern NO-0317; Oslobjorn.hoyland@stv.uio.no

Abstract

Abstract. We analyze legislative voting in the 35th (1994–1997), 38th (2004–2005), and 39th (2006–2008) Canadian Parliaments. Using Poole's (2005) optimal classification algorithm, we locate MPs and their parties in a two-dimensional geometric model. The first dimension represents the division between governing and opposition parties that has been found in similar parliamentary systems. The second dimension captures the opposition between the Bloc Québécois and the rest of the legislature. We find a clear separation between the Reform party (and later the Conservative party) and the Bloc Québécois in the 35th and 38th Parliaments, with the Liberal and the New Democratic parties occupying the centre. However, in the 39th Parliament, the ordering changes with the Conservatives and the New Democrats near the centre, and Liberal and Bloc MPs occupying the extremes. We explain this change by the capacity of the governing party to control the legislative agenda and the recent minority governments in the House of Commons.

Résumé. Nous analysons le vote législatif au trente-cinquième (1994–1997), au trente-huitième (2004–2005) et au trente-neuvième (2006–2008) Parlement canadien. En utilisant la méthode de classification optimale développée par Poole (2005), nous situons les députés de la Chambre des communes et leurs partis dans un modèle géométrique comprenant deux dimensions. La première dimension représente le conflit entre le gouvernement et les partis d'opposition que l'on retrouve également dans d'autres systèmes parlementaires, alors que la seconde dimension correspond à l'opposition régionale qui existe entre le Bloc Québécois et les partis fédéraux. Nous constatons une nette polarité entre le Parti réformiste (et plus tard le Parti conservateur) et le Bloc Québécois au trente-cinquième et au trente-huitième Parlement, alors que le Parti libéral et le Nouveau Parti démocratique se trouvent au centre. Cependant, au trente-neuvième Parlement, nous observons un changement dans la polarité régionale, puisque ce sont maintenant les Libéraux et les Bloquistes qui occupent les deux extrémités, alors que les Conservateurs et les Néodémocrates se situent au centre. Nous expliquons ces mouvements par la capacité du gouvernement de contrôler l'agenda législatif et par les récents gouvernements minoritaires à la Chambre des communes.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Canadian Political Science Association 2011

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Bélanger, Éric, and Godbout, Jean-François. 2010. “Why Do Parties Merge? The Case of the Conservative Party of Canada.” Parliamentary Affairs 63(1): 4165.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blais, André, Gidengil, Elisabeth, Nadeau, Richard and Nevitte, Neil. 2002. Anatomy of a Liberal Victory: Making Sense of the Vote in the 2000 Canadian Election. Peterborough: Broadview Press.Google Scholar
Carty, R. Kenneth, Cross, William and Young, Lisa. 2000. Rebuilding Canadian Party Politics. Vancouver: UBC Press.Google Scholar
Clinton, Joshua. 2007. “Lawmaking and Roll Calls.” Journal of Politics 69(2): 455–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clinton, Joshua, Jackman, Simon and Rivers, Doug. 2004. “The Statistical Analysis of Roll Call Data.” American Political Science Review 98(2): 355–70.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davis, Otto A., Hinich, Melvin J. and Ordeshook, Peter C.. 1970. “An expository development of a mathematical model of the electoral process.” American Political Science Review 64(2): 426–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Docherty, David C. 1997. Mr Smith Goes to Ottawa. Vancouver: University of British Columbia Press.Google Scholar
Flanagan, Thomas. 1998. Game Theory and Canadian Politics. Toronto: University of Toronto Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heckman, James J. and Snyder, James M. Jr. 1997. “Linear probability models of the demand for attributes with an empirical application to estimating the preferences of legislators.” The RAND Journal of Economics 28: S142S189.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hix, Simon. 2008. “Book Review: Spatial Models of Parliamentary Voting.” Party Politics 14(1): 133–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hix, Simon, and Jun, Hae-Won. 2009. “Party Behaviour in the Parliamentary Arena: The Case of the Korean National Assembly.” Party Politics 15(6): 667–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hix, Simon and Noury, Abdul. 2007. “Government-Opposition of Left-Right? The Institutional Determinants of Voting in Eight Parliaments.” Paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, Chicago.Google Scholar
Hix, Simon, Noury, Abdul G. and Roland, Gérard. 2007. Democratic politics in the European Parliament. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hug, Simon. (2010). “Selection Effects in Roll Call Votes.” British Journal of Political Science 40(1): 225–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jenkins, Jeffery A. 1999. “Examining the Bonding Effects of Party: A Comparative Analysis of Roll-Call Voting in the US and Confederate Houses.” American Journal of Political Science 43(4): 1144–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnston, Richard. 2008. “Polarized Pluralism in the Canadian Party System: Presidential Address to the Canadian Political Science Association, June 5, 2008.” Canadian Journal of Political Science 41(4): 815–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnston, Richard, Blais, André, Brady, Henry E. and Crête, Jean. 1992. Letting the People Decide: Dynamics of a Canadian Election. Montreal: McGill-Queen's University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kam, Christopher. 2001. “Do Ideological Preferences Explain Parliamentary Behaviour? Evidence from Great Britain and Canada.” Journal of Legislative Studies 7(4): 89126CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kam, Christopher. 2009. Party Discipline and Parliamentary Government. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laver, Michael and Shepsle, Kenneth A.. 1996. Making and Breaking Governments: Cabinets and Legislatures in Parliamentary Democracies. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laycock, David. 2002. The New Right and Democracy in Canada. Toronto: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Morgenstern, Scott and Nacif, Benito. 2002. Legislative Politics in Latin America. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Poole, Keith T. 2005. Spatial Models of Parliamentary Voting. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Poole, Keith T. and Rosenthal, Howard. 1997. Congress: A Political-Economic History of Roll Call Voting. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Poole, Keith T. and Rosenthal, Howard. 2007. Ideology and Congress. rev. ed.New Brunswick NJ: Transaction Publishers.Google Scholar
Poole, Keith, Lewis, Jeffrey, Lo, James and Carroll, Royce. 2009. OC Roll Call Analysis Software. Technical report. UCLA: CRAN repository.Google Scholar
Rosenthal, Howard and Voeten, Erik. 2004. “Analyzing Roll Calls with Perfect Spatial Voting: France 1946–1958.” American Journal of Political Science 48(3): 620–32.Google Scholar
Sircar, Indraneel and Høyland, Bjørn. 2010. “The Development of Political Party Legislative Dynamics in the Irish Free State Seanad (1922–1936).” Party Politics 16(1): 89110.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Spirling, Arthur and McLean, Iain. 2006. “The Rights and Wrongs of Roll Calls.” Government and Opposition 41(4): 581–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Spirling, Arthur and McLean, Iain. 2007. “UK OC OK? Interpreting Optimal Classification Scores for the UK House of Commons.” Political Analysis 15(1): 8596.CrossRefGoogle Scholar