Hostname: page-component-7c8c6479df-xxrs7 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-03-19T05:16:13.568Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Polecats, lions, and foxes: Coasian bargaining theory and attempts to legitimate the Union as a constrained form of political power

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  25 February 2011

Christopher Lord*
Affiliation:
Professor, ARENA (The Centre for European Studies), The University of Oslo, Blindern, Oslo, Norway

Abstract

It is often supposed that the European Union (EU) can be legitimated as a Pareto-improving bargain between its member states. This paper explores the assumptions of social choice and political philosophy that lie behind that claim. Starting out from a republican view that a polity needs to satisfy standards of non-arbitrariness if it is to be legitimate, the paper begins by explaining why ‘Coasian’ assumptions of Pareto improvement are so important to arguments for the continued indirect legitimacy of the EU by its member states. The paper then identifies four reasons from the social choice literature why attempts to follow a ‘Coasian’ pathway to Pareto improvement may fail to deliver forms of collective choice at the European level that are non-arbitrary from the point of view of all member state governments: non-neutral starting points, preference drift, indivisibilities, and multiple equilibria. These problems are, in turn, used to identify difficulties that mechanisms of indirect legitimation are likely to encounter in meeting two key conditions political philosophers specify for the non-arbitrary exercise of political power, namely, political justice and ‘democratic self-legislation’.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © European Consortium for Political Research 2011

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Arrow, K. (1973 [1967]), ‘Values and collective decision-making’, in E. Phelps (ed.), Economic Justice, Harmondsworth: Penguin, pp. 117136.Google Scholar
Barker, R. (2003), ‘Legitimacy, legitimation and the European Union: what crisis?’, in P. Craig and R. Rawlings (eds), Law and Administration in Europe. Essays in Honour of Carol Harlow, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Barry, B. (1995), Justice as Impartiality: A Treatise on Social Justice Volume II, Oxford: Clarendon.Google Scholar
Bartolini, S. (2005), Restructuring Europe: Centre Formation, System Building and Political Structuring between the Nation State and the European Union, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Beetham, D.Lord, C. (1998), Legitimacy and the European Union, Harlow, Essex: Addison, Wesley, Longman.Google Scholar
Bellamy, R. (2007), Political Constitutionalism, A Republican Defence of the Consitutionality of Democracy, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Bohman, J. (2007), ‘Democratizing the transnational polity, the European Union and the presuppositions of democracy. How to reconstitute democracy in Europe? Proceedings from the Recon Opening Conference’, in E.-O. Eriksen and J.-E. Fossum (eds), How to Reconstitute Democracy in Europe? Proceedings from the Recon Opening Conference, Oslo: Recon/ARENA, pp. 6589.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J.Tullock, G. (1962), The Calculus of Consent. Logical Foundations of Constitutional Democracy, Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Coase, R. (1960), ‘The problem of social cost’, Journal of Law and Economics 3(1): 144.Google Scholar
Dunn, J. (2001), The Cunning of Unreason, Making Sense of Politics, London: Harper Collins.Google Scholar
Eriksen, E.-O. (2009), The Unfinished Democratization of Europe, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Eriksen, E.-O., Fossum, J.-E. (2007), ‘Reconstituting European Democracy’, ARENA Working Paper 01/2007.Google Scholar
Føllesdal, A. (2004), Legitimacy Theories of the European Union. ARENA Working Papers 04/15, Oslo: ARENA.Google Scholar
Forst, R. (2007), Das Recht auf Rechtfertigung. Elemente einer Konstruktivistischen Theorie der Gerechtigkeit, Frankfurt am Main: Suhrkamp.Google Scholar
Garrett, G. (1995), ‘The politics of legal integration in the European Union’, International Organisation 49(1): 171181.Google Scholar
Gaus, D. (2009), Der Sinn Von Demokratie. Die Dikurstheorie der Demokratie und die Debatte über die Legitimät der EU. Frankfurt: Campus Verlag.Google Scholar
Grant, R., Keohane, R. (2005), ‘Accountability and abuses of power in world politics’, American Political Science Review 99(1): 2943.Google Scholar
Habermas, J. (1996), Between Facts and Norms, Cambridge: Polity.Google Scholar
Hix, S. (1999), ‘Dimensions and alignments in European Union politics: cognitive constraints and Partisan responses’, European Journal of Political Research 35: 69109.Google Scholar
Inman, R.Rubinfeld, D. (1997), ‘The political economy of federalism’, in D. Mueller (ed.), Perspectives on Public Choice, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 73105.Google Scholar
Locke, J. (1924 [1690]), Two Treatises of Government, London: Everyman.Google Scholar
Mair, P. (2005), ‘Popular democracy and the European Union polity’. European Governance Papers (EUROGOV), no. C-05-03. Retrieved 11 September 2010 from http://www.connex-network.org/eurogov/pdf/egp-connex-C-05-03.pdfGoogle Scholar
Majone, G. (2001), ‘Two logics of delegation: agency and fiduciary relations in EU governance’, European Union Politics 2(1): 103121.Google Scholar
Majone, G. (2005), Dilemmas of European Integration. The Ambiguities and Pitfalls of Integration by Stealth, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Mattila, M.Lane, J.-E. (2001), ‘Why unanimity in the council? A roll-call analysis of council voting’, European Union Politics 2(1): 3153.Google Scholar
McKelvey, R. (1976), ‘Intransitivities in multidimensional voting models and some implications for agenda-control’, Journal of Economic Theory 12(3): 472482.Google Scholar
Mill, J.S. (1972 [1861]), Utilitarianism, on Liberty and Considerations on Representative Government, London: Dent.Google Scholar
Moravcsik, A. (1993), ‘Preferences and power in the European community: a liberal intergovernmentalist approach’, Journal of Common Market Studies 31(4): 473524.Google Scholar
Moravcsik, A. (1998), The Choice for Europe: Social Purpose and State Power from Messina to Maastricht, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Moravcsik, A. (2005), ‘The European constitutional compromise’, EUSA Review 18(2): 16.Google Scholar
Offe, C (1998), ‘Demokratie und Wohlfahrtstaat: eine europäische Regimereform unter dem stress der europäischen integration’, Swiss Political Science Review 4(4): 3556.Google Scholar
Olsen, J. (2007), Europe in Search of Political Order, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Parisi, F. (2003), ‘Political Coase Theorem’, Public Choice (115): 136.Google Scholar
Pettit, P. (1997), Republicanism: A Theory of Freedom and Government, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Pierson, P. (2000), ‘Increasing returns, path dependence and the study of politics’, American Political Science Review 94(2): 251267.Google Scholar
Plamenatz, J. (1973), Democracy and Illusion: An Examination of Certain Aspects of Modern Democratic Theory, London: Longman.Google Scholar
Pollack, M. (2003), The Engines of European Integration. Delegation, Agency and Agenda-Setting in the EU, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Rae, D (1975), ‘The limits of consensual decision’, American Political Science Review 69(4): 12701294.Google Scholar
Rawls, J. (1971), A Theory of Justice, Cambridge MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Rawls, J. (1973 [1967]), ‘Distributive justice’, in E. Phelps (ed.), Economic Justice, Harmondsworth: Penguin, pp. 319362.Google Scholar
Rawls, J. (1993), Political Liberalism, New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Rawls, J. (2001), Justice as Fairness, A Restatement, Harvard: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Richardson, H. (2003), Democratic Autonomy: Public Reasoning about the Ends of Policy, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Riker, W. (1986), The Art of Political Manipulation, Yale: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Rousseau, J.-J. (1973 [1762]), The Social Contract or Principles of Political Right, London: Everyman.Google Scholar
Sabel, C., Zeitlin, J. (2007), ‘Learning from difference. The new architecture of experimentalist governance in the European Union’, European Governance Papers (EUROGOV). No C-07-02. Retrieved 11 September 2010 from http://www.connex-network.org/eurogov/pdf/egp-connex-C-07-02.pdfGoogle Scholar
Scharpf, F. (1999), Governing in Europe: Effective and Democratic?, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Scharpf, F. (2006), ‘The joint-decision trap revisited’, Journal of Common Market Studies 44(4): 845864.Google Scholar
Scharpf, F. (2007), ‘Reflections on multilevel legitimacy’, EUSA Review 20(3): 29.Google Scholar
Scharpf, F. (2009), ‘Legitimacy in the multilevel European polity’, European Political Science Review 1(2): 173204.Google Scholar
Schmidt, V. (2006), Democracy in Europe, The EU and National Polities, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Sen, A. (1970), Collective Choice and Social Welfare, San Francisco: Holden Day.Google Scholar
Sen, A. (2002), Rationality and Freedom, Cambridge, MA: Belknap/Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Sen, A. (2009), The Idea of Justice, Harvard: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Shapiro, I. (1996), Democracy’s Place, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Streeck, W.Thelen, K. (eds) (2005), Beyond Continuity, Institutional Change in Advanced Political Economies, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Tallberg, J. (2003), European Governance and Supranational Institutions, Making States Comply, London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Weiler, J. (1997), ‘Legitimacy and democracy of Union governance’, in G. Edwards and A. Pijpers (eds), The Politics of European Union Treaty Reform, London: Pinter.Google Scholar