Hostname: page-component-7c8c6479df-r7xzm Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-03-27T22:46:14.278Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Slide to Protectionism in the Great Depression: Who Succumbed and Why?

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 December 2010

Barry Eichengreen*
Affiliation:
Professor of Economics, University of California at Berkeley, Berkeley, CA 94720. E-mail: eichengr@econ.berkeley.edu.
Douglas A. Irwin*
Affiliation:
Professor of Economics, Dartmouth College, Hanover, NH 03755. E-mail: douglas.irwin@dartmouth.edu.

Abstract

The Great Depression was marked by a severe outbreak of protectionist trade policies. But contrary to the presumption that all countries scrambled to raise trade barriers, there was substantial cross-country variation in the movement to protectionism. Specifically, countries that remained on the gold standard resorted to tariffs, import quotas, and exchange controls to a greater extent than countries that went off gold. Just as the gold standard constraint on monetary policy is critical to understanding macroeconomic developments in this period, exchange rate policies help explain changes in trade policy.

Type
ARTICLES
Copyright
Copyright © The Economic History Association 2010

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Accominotti, Olivier. “Contagion and the Sterling Crisis of 1931.” Unpublished Manuscript, UC Berkeley and Sciences-Po, March 2009.Google Scholar
Anderson, James, and Peter Neary, J.. Measuring the Restrictiveness of International Trade Policy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2005.Google Scholar
Anderson, James, and van Wincoop, Eric. “Trade Costs.” Journal of Economic Literature 42, no. 3 (2004): 691–751.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernanke, Ben. “The Macroeconomics of the Great Depression: A Comparative Approach.” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 27, no. 1 (1995): 1–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bordo, Michael D. and Redish, Angela. “Credible Commitment and Exchange Rate Stability: Canada's Interwar Experience.” Canadian Journal of Economics 23, no. 2 (1990): 357–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Capie, Forrest. Depression and Protectionism: Britain Between the Wars. London: George Allen & Unwin, 1983.Google Scholar
Chernyshoff, Natalia, Jacks, David S., and Taylor, Alan M.. “Stuck on Gold: Real Exchange Rate Volatility and the Rise and Fall of the Gold Standard, 1875—1939.” Journal of International Economics 77, no. 2 (2009): 195–205.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Choudhri, Ehsan, and Kochin, Levis. “The Exchange Rate and the International Transmission of Business Cycle Disturbances: Some Evidence from the Great Depression.” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 12, no. 4 (1980): 565–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clemens, Michael A. and Williamson, Jeffrey G.. “Why Did the Tariff-Growth Correlation Change After 1950?” Journal of Economic Growth 9, no. 1 (2004): 5–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eichengreen, Barry. “Keynes and Protection.” The Journal of Economic History 44, no. 2 (1984): 363–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eichengreen, Barry. “Sterling and the Tariff, 1929—1931.” In Elusive Stability: Essays in the History of International Finance, 1991—1939. New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eichengreen, Barry. Golden Fetters: The Gold Standard and the Great Depression, 1919—1939. New York: Oxford University Press, 1992.Google Scholar
Eichengreen, Barry, and Flandreau, Marc. “The Rise and Fall of the Dollar, or When Did the Dollar Replace Sterling as the Leading International Currency?” NBER Working Paper No. 14154, Cambridge, MA, July 2008.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eichengreen, Barry, and Irwin, Douglas A.. “Trade Blocs, Currency Blocs, and the Reorientation of World Trade in the 1930s.” Journal of International Economics 38, no. 1 (1995): 1–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eichengreen, Barry, and Sachs, Jeffrey. “Exchange Rates and Economic Recovery in the 1930s.” The Journal of Economic History 45, no. 4 (1985): 925–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eichengreen, Barry, and Uzan, Marc. “The 1933 World Economic Conference as an Instance of Failed International Cooperation.” In Double-Edged Diplomacy: International Bargaining and Domestic Politics, edited by Evans, Peter, Jacobson, Harold, and Putnam, Robert, 171–206. Berkeley: University of California Press, 1992.Google Scholar
Estevadeordal, Antoni, Frantz, Brian, and Taylor, Alan M.. “The Rise and Fall of World Trade, 1870—1939.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 118, no. 2 (2003): 359–407.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ferguson, Thomas, and Temin, Peter. “Made in Germany: The German Currency Crisis of 1931.” Research in Economic History 21 (2003): 1–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garside, W. R.“Party Politics, Political Economy, and British Protectionism, 1919—1932.” History 83 (1998): 47–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haber, Stephen, Razo, Armando, and Maurer, Noel. The Politics of Property Rights: Political Instability, Credible Commitments, and Economic Growth in Mexico, 1876—1929. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2004.Google Scholar
Hamilton, James. “Monetary Factors in the Great Depression.” Journal of Monetary Economics 19, no. 2 (1987): 145–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Irwin, Douglas A.“Changes in U.S. Tariffs: The Role of Import Prices and Commercial Policies.” American Economic Review 88, no. 4 (1998): 1015–26.Google Scholar
Irwin, Douglas A.Peddling Protectionism: Smoot-Hawley and the Great Depression. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2011.Google Scholar
Jacks, David S., Meissner, Christopher M., and Novy, Dennis. “Trade Costs, 1870—2000.” American Economic Review 98, no. 2 (2008): 529–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jacks, David S., Meissner, Christopher M., and Novy, Dennis. “Trade Booms, Trade Busts, and Trade Costs.” NBER Working Paper No. 15267, Cambridge, MA, August 2009.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jacks, David S., Meissner, Christopher M., and Novy, Dennis. “Trade Costs in the First Wave of Globalization.” Explorations in Economic History 47, no. 2 (2010): 127–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
James, Harold. The German Slump: Politics and Economics, 1924—1936. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1986.Google Scholar
James, Harold. The End of Globalization. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2001.Google Scholar
Johansen, Hans Christian. The Danish Economy in the Twentieth Century. London: Croom Helm, 1987.Google Scholar
Johnson, H. Clark. Gold, France, and the Great Depression. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 1997.Google Scholar
Kee, Hiau L., Nicita, Alessandro, and Olarreaga, Marcelo. “Import Demand Elasticities and Trade Distortions.” Review of Economics and Statistics 90, no. 4 (2008): 666–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kindleberger, Charles P.The World in Depression, 1929—1939. Revised edition. Berkeley: University of California Press, 1986.Google Scholar
Kindleberger, Charles P. “Commercial Policy Between the Wars.” In The Cambridge Economic History of Europe, Volume 8: The Industrial Economies: The Development of Economic and Social Policies, edited by Mathias, Peter and Pollard, Sidney, 161–96. New York: Cambridge University Press, 1989.Google Scholar
League of Nations. World Economic Survey 1932/33. Geneva: League of Nations, 1933.Google Scholar
League of Nations. Report on Exchange Controls. Geneva: League of Nations, 1938.Google Scholar
League of Nations. Money and Banking, 1937/38. Geneva: League of Nations, 1939.Google Scholar
League of Nations. Review of World Trade, 1938. Geneva: League of Nations, 1939.Google Scholar
League of Nations. World Economic Survey, 1938/39. Geneva: League of Nations, 1939.Google Scholar
League of Nations. World Production and Prices, 1938/39. Geneva: League of Nations, 1939.Google Scholar
League of Nations. Commercial Policy in the Interwar Period: International Proposals and National Policies. Geneva: League of Nations, 1942.Google Scholar
League of Nations. Network of World Trade. Geneva: League of Nations, 1942.Google Scholar
Lopez-Cordova, J. Ernesto, and Meissner, Christopher M.. “Exchange-Rate Regimes and International Trade: Evidence from the Classical Gold Standard Era.” American Economic Review 93, no. 1 (2003): 344–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McDonald, Judith, Patrick O'Brien, Anthony, and Callahan, Colleen. “Trade Wars: Canada's Reaction to the Smoot-Hawley Tariff.” The Journal of Economic History 57, no. 4 (1997): 802–26.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maddison, Angus. Historical Statistics on the World Economy, 1—2008AD. Available at http://www.ggdc.net/maddison/Historical_Statistics/vertical-file_02-2010.xls (3 May 2010).Google Scholar
Madsen, Jakob B.“Trade Barriers and the Collapse of World Trade During the Great Depression.” Southern Economic Journal 67, no. 4 (2001): 848–68.Google Scholar
Mitchell, Brian R.International Historical Statistics: Africa, Asia, & Oceania, 1750—2005. New York: Palgrave Macmillan, 2007a.Google Scholar
Mitchell, Brian R.International Historical Statistics: Europe, 1750—2005. New York: Palgrave Macmillan, 2007b.Google Scholar
Mitchell, Brian R.International Historical Statistics: The Americas, 1750—2005. New York: Palgrave Macmillan, 2007c.Google Scholar
Myers, Margaret. Paris as a Financial Center. London: P. S. King, 1937.Google Scholar
Obstfeld, Maurice, Shambaugh, Jay C., and Taylor, Alan M.. “Monetary Sovereignty, Exchange Rates, and Capital Controls: The Trilemma in the Interwar Period.” Staff Papers 51 (2004): 75–108.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Obstfeld, Maurice, and Taylor, Alan M.. “The Great Depression as a Watershed: International Capital Mobility Over the Long Run.” In The Defining Moment: The Great Depression and the American Economy in the Twentieth Century, edited by Bordo, Michael, Goldin, Claudia, and White, Eugene, 353–402. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1998.Google Scholar
Peden, George. The Treasury View and British Public Policy, 1906—1959. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2000.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ritschl, Albrecht, and Wolf, Nikolaus. “Endogeneity of Currency Areas and Trade Blocs: Evidence from the Interwar Period.” CEPR Working Paper No. 4112, 2003.Google Scholar
Rodríguez, Francisco, and Rodrik, Dani. “Trade Policy and Economic Growth: A Skeptic's Guide to the Cross-National Evidence.” In NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2000, edited by Bernanke, Ben and Rogoff, Kenneth S., 261–325. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2001.Google Scholar
Salmon, Patrick. “Paternalism or Partnership? Finance and Trade in Anglo-Danish Relations in the 1930s.” In Britain and Denmark: Political, Economic, and Cultural Relations in the Nineteenth and Twentieth Centuries, edited by Sevaldsen, Jorgen, 231–50. Copenhagen: Museum Tusculanum Press, 2003.Google Scholar
Shearer, Ronald A. and Clark, Carolyn. “Canada and the Interwar Gold Standard: Monetary Policy Without a Central Bank.” In A Retrospective on the Classical Gold Standard, edited by Bordo, Michael D. and Schwartz, Anna J., 277–302. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1984.Google Scholar
Temin, Peter. Lessons from the Great Depression. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1989.Google Scholar
Temin, Peter. “The German Crisis of 1931: Evidence and Tradition.” Cliometrica 2, no. 1 (2008): 5–17.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wandschneider, Kirsten. “The Stability of the Interwar Gold Standard: Did Politics Matter?” The Journal of Economic History 68, no. 1 (2008): 151–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wei, Shang-Jin, and Zhang, Zeiwei. “Collateral Damage: Exchange Controls and International Trade.” Journal of International Money and Finance 26, no. 5 (2007): 841–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Whittlesey, C. R.“Import Quotas in the United States.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 52, no. 1 (1937): 37–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, Philip. National Crisis and National Government: British Politics, the Economy and Empire, 1926—1932. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1992.Google Scholar
Wolf, Holger C. and Yousef, Tarik M.. “Breaking the Fetters: Why Did Countries Exit the Interwar Gold Standard?” In The New Comparative Economic History: Essays in Honor of Jeffrey G. Williamson, edited by Hatton, Timothy J., O'Rourke, Kevin H., and Taylor, Alan M., 241–66. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 2007.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wolf, Nikolaus. “Scylla and Charybdis: Explaining Europe's Exit from Gold, January 1928—December 1936.” Explorations in Economic History 45, no. 4 (2008): 383–401.CrossRefGoogle Scholar