Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-wq2xx Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-17T12:48:55.763Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Why Small, Centrist Third Parties Motivate Policy Divergence by Major Parties

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  25 August 2006

JAMES ADAMS
Affiliation:
University of California
SAMUEL MERRILL
Affiliation:
Wilkes University

Abstract

Plurality-based elections between two major parties or candidates sometimes feature small, centrist, third parties. We modify the standard two-party spatial model of policy-seeking parties to incorporate a centrist third party, and we show that the presence of such a party—even if it has no chance of winning—motivates the major parties to propose policies that are much more divergent than without the third party. We derive explicit formulas for party locations at a three-party equilibrium and provide necessary and sufficient conditions for existence of that equilibrium. We show that, over time, the major parties can be expected to shift their policies in the same direction relative to each other but in the opposite direction relative to the minor party. The predictions of this model are compared with estimates of party policy locations during appropriate periods in postwar Britain.

Type
ARTICLES
Copyright
© 2006 by the American Political Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Adams James, Michael Clark, Lawrence Ezrow, and Garrett Glasgow. 2004. “Understanding Change and Stability in Party Ideologies: Do Parties Respond to Public Opinion or to Past Election Results?British Journal of Political Science 34 (October): 589610.Google Scholar
Adams James, Samuel Merrill III, and Bernard Grofman. 2005. A Unified Theory of Party Competition: A Cross-National Analysis Integrating Spatial and Behavioral Factors Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press.
Baron David. 1994. “Electoral Competition with Informed and Uninformed Voters.” American Political Science Review 88 (March): 3347.Google Scholar
Brams Steven, and Samuel Merrill III, 1983. “Equilibrium Strategies for Final-Offer Arbitration: There is No Median Convergence.” Management Science 29 (August): 92741.Google Scholar
Brams Steven, and Samuel Merrill III., 1991. “Final-Offer Arbitration with a Bonus.” European Journal of Political Economy 7 (April): 7992.Google Scholar
Budge Ian. 1994. “A New Theory of Party Competition: Uncertainty, Ideology, and Party Equilibria Viewed Temporally and Comparatively.” British Journal of Political Science 24 (July): 44367.Google Scholar
Budge Ian, Hans-Dieter Klingemann, Andrea Volkens, Eric Tannenbaum, and Judith Bara (eds.). 2001. Mapping Policy Preferences: Estimates for Parties, Electors, and Governments 1945–1998. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Burden Barry. 2004. “Candidate Positioning in U.S. Congressional Elections.” British Journal of Political Science 34 (April): 21127.Google Scholar
Calvert Randall. 1985. “Robustness of the Multidimensional Voting Model: Candidates, Motivations, Uncertainty, and Convergence.” American Journal of Political Science 29 (February): 6995.Google Scholar
Cook Chris. 1998. A Short History of the Liberal Party, 1900–1996. fifth edition. London: Macmillan.
Cox Gary. 1984. “An Expected-Utility Model of Electoral Competition.Quality and Quantity 18 (August): 33749.Google Scholar
Downs Anthony. 1957. An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper and Row.
Eaton B. Curtis, and Richard G. Lipsey. 1975. “The Principle of Minimum Differentiation Reconsidered: Some New Developments in the Theory of Spatial Competition.” Review of Economic Studies 42 (January): 2749.Google Scholar
Erikson Robert, Michael MacKuen, and James Stimson. 2002. The Macro Polity. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.
Fowler James, and Oleg Smirnov. n.d. Mandates, Parties, and Voters: How Elections Shape the Future. Book manuscript.
Gerber Elizabeth, and John Jackson. 1993. “Endogenous Preferences and the Study of Institutions.” American Political Science Review 87 (September): 63956.Google Scholar
Groseclose Timothy. 2001. “A Model of Candidate Location when One Candidate Has a Valence Advantage. American Journal of Political Science 45 (October): 86286.Google Scholar
Hinich Melvin, and Michael Munger. 1997. Analytical Politics. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.
Huber John, and Ronald Inglehart. 1995. “Expert Interpretations of Party Space and Party Locations in 42 Societies.” Party Politics 1 (January): 73111.Google Scholar
Kim Hee-min, and Richard C. Fording. 2001. “Extending the Party Estimates to Governments and Electors.” In Mapping Policy Preferences: Estimates for Parties, Electors, and Governments 1945–1998. Ian Budge, Hans Dieter Klingemann, Andrea Volkens, Eric Tannenbaum, and Judith Bara, eds. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Lin Tse-min James Enelow, and Han Dorussen. 1999. “Equilibrium in Multiparty Probabilistic Spatial Voting.” Public Choice 98 (July): 5982.Google Scholar
McDonald Michael, and Ian Budge. 2006. Elections, Parties, and Democracy: Conferring the Median Mandate. Oxford University Press.
Meguid Bonnie. 2005. “Competition Between Unequals: The Role of Mainstream Party Strategy in Niche Party Success.” American Political Science Review 99 (August): 34759.Google Scholar
Merrill Samuel III, and James Adams. 2002. “Centrifugal Incentives in Multicandidate Elections.” Journal of Theoretical Politics 14 (July): 273300.Google Scholar
Nagel Jack. 2001. “Center-Party Strength and Major-Party Polarization in Britain.Presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, San Francisco, CA, August 30–September 2.
Powell G. Bingham. 2000. Elections as Instruments of Democracy. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Roemer John. 2001. Political Competition: Theory and Applications. Harvard University Press.
Schofield Norman, and Itai Sened. 2005. “Multiparty Competition in Israel, 1988–1996.” British Journal of Political Science 35 (October): 63563.Google Scholar
Wittman Donald. 1973. “Parties as Utility Maximizers.” American Political Science Review 67 (June): 49098.Google Scholar
Wittman Donald. 1977. “Candidates with Policy Preferences: A Dynamic Model.” Journal of Economic Theory 14 (February): 18089.Google Scholar
Wittman Donald. 1983. “Candidate Motivation: A Synthesis of Alternatives.” American Political Science Review 77 (March): 14257.Google Scholar
Wittman Donald. 1990. “Spatial Strategies When Candidates have Policy Preferences.” In Advances in the Spatial Theory of Voting. ed. James Enelow and Melvin Hinich. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.