Hostname: page-component-7c8c6479df-5xszh Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-03-27T23:25:56.826Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Judicial Lobbying: The Politics of Labor Law Constitutional Interpretation

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 February 2006

MATIAS IARYCZOWER
Affiliation:
California Institute of Technology
PABLO T. SPILLER
Affiliation:
Haas School of Business, University of California, Berkeley and NBER
MARIANO TOMMASI
Affiliation:
Universidad de San Andrés and CEDI

Abstract

This paper links the theory of interest groups influence over the legislature with that of congressional control over the judiciary. The resulting framework reconciles the theoretical literature of lobbying with the negative available evidence on the impact of lobbying over legislative outcomes, and sheds light to the determinants of lobbying in separation-of-powers systems. We provide conditions for judicial decisions to be sensitive to legislative lobbying, and find that lobbying falls the more divided the legislature is on the relevant issues. We apply this framework to analyze supreme court labor decisions in Argentina, and find results consistent with the predictions of the theory.

Type
ARTICLES
Copyright
© 2006 by the American Political Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Ainsworth Scott. 1993. “Regulating Lobbyists and Interest Group Influence.”The Journal of Politics 55 (February): 4156.Google Scholar
Austen-Smith David. 1993. “Information and Influence: Lobbying for Agendas and Votes.”American Journal of Political Science 37 (August): 799833.Google Scholar
Ansolabehere Stephen D., John M. de Figueiredo, and James M. Snyder. 2003. “Why Is There So Little Money in Politics?Journal of Economic Perspectives 17 (Winter): 10530.Google Scholar
Banks Jeffrey S., and Joel Sobel. 1987. “Equilibrium Selection in Signaling Games.” Econometrica 55 (May): 64761.Google Scholar
Baron David. 1994. “Spatial Electoral Competition and Campaign Contributions with Informed and Uninformed Voters.” American Political Science Review 88 (March): 3347.Google Scholar
Bergara Mario, Barak D. Richman, and Pablo T. Spiller. 2003. “Modeling Supreme Court Strategic Decision Making: The Congressional Constraint.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 28 (May): 24780.Google Scholar
Bernheim Douglas. 1994. “A Theory of Conformity.” Journal of Political Economy 102 (October): 84177.Google Scholar
Cho Inn Koo, and David M. Kreps. 1987. “Signaling Games and Stable Equilibria.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 102 (May): 179221.Google Scholar
de Figuereido John M. 2002. “Lobbying and Information in Politics.” Business and Politics 4 (2): 12529.Google Scholar
Denzau Arthur T., and Michael C. Munger. 1986. “Legislators and Interest Groups: How Unorganized Interests Get Represented.” American Political Science Review 80 (March): 89106.Google Scholar
Fernandez Arturo. 1988. Las Practicas Sociopoliticas del Sindicalismo (1955–1985). Buenos Aires: Centro Editor de America Latina.
Fudenberg Drew, and Jean Tirole. 1998. Game Theory, 6th ed. Cambridge: The MIT Press.
Gely Rafael, and Pablo T. Spiller. 1990. “A Rational Choice Theory of Supreme Court Statutory Decisions with Applications to the State Farm and Grove City Cases.” Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 6 (Fall): 263300.Google Scholar
Gely Rafael, and Pablo T. Spiller. 1992. “The political economy of supreme court constitutional decisions: The case of Roosevelt's court-packing plan.” International Review of Law and Economics 12 (March): 4567.Google Scholar
Greene William. 2000. Econometric Anaysis, 4th ed. New Jersey: Prentice Hall.
Helmke Gretchen. 2002. “The Logic of Strategic Defection: Court-Executive Relations in Argentina Under Dictatorship and Democracy.” American Political Science Review 96 (June): 291303.Google Scholar
Iaryczower Matias. 2005. “Contestable Leaderships: Party Discipline and Vote Buying in Legislatures.” Typescript. University of California, Los Angeles.
Iaryczower Matias, Pablo T. Spiller, and Mariano Tommasi. 2002. “Judicial Independence in Unstable Environments.” American Journal of Political Science 46 (October): 699716.Google Scholar
Jones Mark. 2002. “Explaining the High Level of Party Discipline in the Argentine Congress.” In Legislative Politics in Latin America, ed. Scott Morgenstern and Benito Nacif. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Lohmann Susanne. 1995. “Information, Access and Contributions: A Signaling Model of Lobbying.” Public Choice 85 (December): 26784.Google Scholar
McGuire James. 1995. “Political Parties and Democracy in Argentina.” In Building Democratic Institutions: Party Systems in Latin America, ed. Scott Mainwaring and Timothy Scully. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
McGuire James. 1997. Peronism without Peron: Unions, Parties, and Democracy in Argentina. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Nueva Mayoria. 2001. “Argentina: Conflictos Laborales desde 1980.” <http://www.nuevamayoria.com/ES/>.
O'Donnell Guillermo. 2000. “Argentina, Domestic Violence and Economic Data, 1955–1972.” [Computer File]. ICPSR Version. Ann Arbour MI: Inter-University Consortium for Political and Social Research [Distributor], 2000.
Ramey Garey. 1996. “D1 Signaling Equilibria with Multiple Signals and a Continuum of Types.” Journal of Economic Theory 69 (May): 50831.Google Scholar
Rasmusen Eric. 1993. “Lobbying When the Decisión Maker Can Acquire Independent Information.” Public Choice 77 (December): 899913.Google Scholar
Rotondaro Ruben. 1971. Realidad y Cambio en el Sindicalismo. Buenos Aires: Pleamar.
Segal Jeffrey A. 1997. “Separation-of-Power Games in the Positive Theory of Congress and Courts.” American Political Science Review 91 (March): 2844.Google Scholar
Snyder James M. Jr. 1990. “Campaign Contributions as Investments: The U.S House of Representatives, 1980-1986.” Journal of Political Economy 98 (December): 1195227.Google Scholar
Snyder James M. Jr. 1991. “On Buying Legislatures.” Economics and Politics 3 (July): 93109.Google Scholar
Snyder James M. Jr. 1992. “Long Term Investing in Politicians, or, Give Early, Give Often.” Journal of Law and Economics 35 (April): 1543.Google Scholar
Staton Jeffrey. 2006. “Constitutional Review and the Selective Promotion of Case Results.” American Journal of Political Science. Forthcoming.
Stratmann Thomas. 1992. “Are Contributors Rational? Untangling Strategies of Political Action Committees.” Journal of Political Economy (June): 64764.Google Scholar
Stratmann Thomas. 1995. “Campaign Contributions and Congressional Voting. Does the Timing of the Contributions Matter? Review of Economics and Statistics 77 (February): 12736.Google Scholar
Stratmann Thomas. 1996. “How Reelection Constituencies Matter: Evidence from Political Action Committees' Contributions and Congressional Voting.” Journal of Law and Economics 39 (October): 60335.Google Scholar
Toma Eugenia F. 1991. “Congressional Influence and the Supreme Court: The Budget as Signaling Device.” Journal of Legal Studies 20 (January): 13146.Google Scholar
Torre Juan Carlos. 1983. Los Sindicatos en el Gobierno, 1973–1976. Buenos Aires, Centro Editor de America Latina.
Vanberg Georg. 2001. “Legislative-Judicial Relations: A Game Theoretic Approach to Constitucional Review.” American Journal of Political Science 45 (April): 34661.Google Scholar