Hostname: page-component-7c8c6479df-5xszh Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-03-28T15:44:53.827Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Institutions matter: but which institutions? And how and why do they change?

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  02 December 2015

ANDREW TYLECOTE*
Affiliation:
Management School, University of Sheffield, Sheffield, England

Abstract

Both political and economic institutions matter for economic growth and development, and are indissolubly connected: sustained economic growth requires far-reaching opening up of the economy and polity to wide participation. This review essay draws on three books which share this view of institutions, to develop an argument on which institutions matter most, and how and why they change. Like them, it uses history as laboratory. North et al. (2009) in Violence and Social Orders focus on Britain, France and the United States, in which change was generally progressive, to study such change from the medieval to the modern period. Jan van Zanden in The Long Road to the Industrial Revolution looks at Europe, 1000–1800, in particular the Netherlands and England, finding regressive as well as progressive change. Acemoglu and Robinson also examine both directions of change, in Why Nations Fail: they range widely in space, but little before the 16th century. All three offer powerful tools of analysis. All have implications for policy-makers in advanced societies who wish to promote the development of ‘inclusive’ institutions elsewhere. Two striking surprises emerge, and one prime mover – an institution with particular power to change others – the medieval Catholic church.

Type
Review Article
Copyright
Copyright © Millennium Economics Ltd 2015 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Acemoglu, D. and Robinson, J. A. (2012), Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity and Poverty, London: Profile Books.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., and Robinson, J. A. (2005), ‘Institutions as a Fundamental Cause of Long-Run Growth’, in Aghion, P. and Durlauf, S. N. (eds.), Handbook of Economic Growth, vol. 1A, Amsterdam: Elsevier, pp. 385472.Google Scholar
Allen, R.C. (2011), Global Economic History: A Very Short Introduction. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carruthers, B. (1990), ‘Politics, Popery and Property: A Comment on North and Weingast’, Journal of Economic History, 50 (3): 693698.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chang, H.-J. (2002), Kicking Away the Ladder, Anthem: London.Google Scholar
Clark, G. (1996), ‘The Political Foundations of Modern Economic Growth: England 1600–1800’, Journal of Interdisciplinary History, 26 (4): 563588.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diamond, J. (2012), ‘What makes countries rich or poor?’, New York Review of Books, June 7th, pp. 70–75.Google Scholar
Economist (2014), ‘Religion in China: cracks in the atheist edifice’, The Economist, Nov 1st.Google Scholar
Hicks, J. R. (1969), A Theory of Economic History, Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Laurence, A. (1994), Women in England 1500–1760: A Social History, London: Weidenfeld and Nicolson.Google Scholar
Leyser, H. (1995), Medieval Women: A Social History of Women in England 450–1500, London: Weidenfeld and Nicolson.Google Scholar
Maddison, Angus (2007), Contours of the World Economy 1–2030 AD: Essays in Macro-Economic History, Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, D.C. (1990), Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance, New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, D. C., Wallis, J. J., and Weingast, B. R. (2009), Violence and Social Orders: A Conceptual Framework for Interpreting Recorded Human History, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O’Day, R. (1996), ‘An Educated Society’, in Morrill, J. (ed.), The Oxford Illustrated History of Tudor and Stuart Britain, Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 119138.Google Scholar
Poole, A. L. (1951), Domesday Book to Magna Carta, 1087–1216, Oxford History of England, Oxford: Clarendon.Google Scholar
van Bavel, B. J. P. (2015), ‘History as a Laboratory to Better Understand the Formation of Institutions’, Journal of Institutional Economics, 11 (1): 6992.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
van Zanden, J. L. (2009), The Long Road to the Industrial Revolution: The European Economy in a Global Perspective, 1000–1800, Leiden and Boston: Brill.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
WBGDG (2003), Gender Equality and the Millennium Development Goals, Washington DC: World Bank Gender and Development Group, April.Google Scholar
Wedgwood, C. V. (1944), William the Silent, London: Cape.Google Scholar
Williamson, J. (1989), ‘What Washington Means by Policy Reform’, in Williamson, J. (ed.), Latin American Readjustment: How Much has Happened, Washington: Institute for International Economics.Google Scholar
World Bank (2001), Social Protection Strategy: From Safety Net to Springboard, Washington DC: World Bank.Google Scholar