Hostname: page-component-7c8c6479df-nwzlb Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-03-28T12:30:19.185Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Congress as manager: oversight hearings and agency morale

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  18 December 2015

John D. Marvel
Affiliation:
School of Policy, Government, and International Affairs, George Mason University, USA E-mail: jmarvel@gmu.edu
Robert J. McGrath
Affiliation:
School of Policy, Government, and International Affairs, George Mason University, USA E-mail: rmcgrat2@gmu.edu
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Federal agencies perform many important tasks, from guarding against terrorist plots to mailing social security checks. A key question is whether Congress can effectively manage such a large and influential bureaucracy. We argue that Congress, in using oversight to ensure agency responsiveness to legislative preferences, risks harming agency morale, which could have negative long-run effects on performance and the implementation of public policy. More specifically, we argue that oversight’s effects on agency morale are conditional on whether oversight is adversarial or friendly. We assess our claims using a novel data set of the frequency and tone of hearings in which federal agencies are called to testify before Congress from 1999 to 2011 and merge it with data on agency autonomy and job satisfaction. Our findings suggest that agency morale is sensitive to congressional oversight attention, and thus speak to questions regarding democratic accountability, congressional policymaking and the implementation of public policy.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
© Cambridge University Press, 2015 

The agencies that comprise the federal government’s executive branch do many things: they protect the environment, guard against foreign and domestic threats to national security, mail millions of social security checks each month and perform many additional functions, some more glamorous than others. Given that the federal bureaucracy is a nonelectoral institution, Congress is charged with overseeing the execution of these tasks. In particular, congressional committees monitor the bureaucracy through oversight hearings, often attempting to increase agency responsiveness to congressional policy preferences. Yet, scholarship has paid scant attention to the possibility that such oversight may have significant managerial consequences. In particular, theory suggests that oversight may, at least conditionally, negatively affect agency morale, particularly as reflected in agencies’ collective senses of autonomy and job satisfaction – that is, an empirical, as well as a theoretical, trade-off may exist between political responsiveness and agency autonomy. We assessed this possibility, examining the link between oversight and survey-based measures of morale, and found that congressional oversight, when it is adversarial in tone, can indeed have negative consequences for the functioning of bureaucracy. Yet, we also found that more “friendly” congressional attention can actually improve agency morale.

Our research speaks to persistent questions concerning the correct balance between politics and administration. The impact of politics on policy implementation has been the subject of long-standing scholarly debate, particularly within public administration (Waldo Reference Waldo1948). Echoing arguments from the Progressive Era (Wilson Reference Wilson1887), contemporary government reform movements such as the New Public Management advance the argument that politics interferes with agencies’ fulfilment of their duties (see, e.g. Light Reference Light2006). On the other hand, some have argued that politics and administration are inextricably intertwined, and that attempts to neatly separate them are hopeless and naive (Waldo Reference Waldo1948; Rosenbloom Reference Rosenbloom1993). By examining whether and under which conditions congressional oversight is related to agency morale, we aim to make an empirical contribution to this debate. We also contribute to the burgeoning public management literature on organisational performance. Although the notion that political actors influence agencies is central to this literature’s prominent theories (e.g. O’Toole and Meier Reference O’Toole and Meier1999; Rainey and Steinbauer Reference Rainey and Steinbauer1999), very little empirical research addresses whether there is in fact a relationship between the activities of these actors and agency morale – a variable that theory and empirical evidence suggest will affect performance.Footnote 1

We seek to synthesise and contribute to two distinct, but related, fields of research. Studies in political science have traditionally been concerned with questions of congressional monitoring and control of bureaucratic outputs and policy (McCubbins and Schwartz Reference McCubbins and Schwartz1984; Bendor et al. Reference Bendor, Taylor and Van Gaalen1985; Moe Reference Moe1989; Ferejohn and Shipan Reference Ferejohn and Shipan1990; Balla Reference Balla1998; Wood and Bohte Reference Wood and Bohte2004). This is a crucially important issue for a democratic system of government. If duly elected political actors must rely on unelected bureaucrats to implement policy programmes, control and responsiveness are normative imperatives (see, e.g. Finer Reference Finer1941). Research in public administration, on the other hand, has focussed on the roles of professional norms and ethics in constraining bureaucratic policy implementation. In this view, public agencies should be subject to internal constraints (the so-called “inner check”), yet minimally encumbered by the intrusion of political actors (Friedrich Reference Friedrich1940). These two perspectives – democratic control of public agencies enforced by external political actors versus professional democratic norms developed through internal disciplineFootnote 2 – are often seen as driving contemporary normative debates across political science and public administration. We seek to test the implicit claim of the latter perspective that political intervention can serve to limit agency discretion in deleterious and counterproductive ways (Behn Reference Behn1995). In particular, we utilise novel data on oversight hearings directed at particular agencies from 1999 through 2011, and assess whether increases in oversight attention affect agencies’ collective feelings of autonomy and job satisfaction.

We begin by discussing agency morale and its importance. As theory suggests that morale is positively associated with agency performance, as well as with work attitudes and work behaviours that feed into performance, we see it as particularly worthy of empirical attention. We then argue that congressional oversight is likely to affect agency morale, but that the direction of these effects should depend on the content and tone of the oversight. Next, we describe our data and empirical strategy, paying particular attention to our measures of oversight and agency morale. After presenting our results, we close with a discussion of our findings’ practical and theoretical implications. The main takeaway is that oversight seems to negatively affect morale, but only when the oversight is adversarial and negative in tone. In fact, we provide evidence that so-called “advocacy” oversight, on the other hand, can actually bolster agency morale (Aberbach Reference Aberbach1990).

The importance of agency morale

Part of the job of any manager, in any organisational setting, is to motivate employees. Doing so involves cultivating employee work attitudes (e.g. job satisfaction, organisational commitment) and behaviours (e.g. arriving to work on time, aiding coworkers) that are thought to be associated with individual- and organisational-level performance. In exercising its oversight function, however, Congress is not necessarily interested in doing these things.Footnote 3 Instead, it is primarily interested in ensuring federal agencies’ responsiveness to legislative preferences.Footnote 4 However, in pursuing responsiveness, Congress can unwittingly harm agency morale. Before fully developing this argument below, we define the empirical focus of our study – agency morale – and discuss its importance for agency performance.

We use the term “agency morale” to denote agency employees’ collective feelings of autonomy and job satisfaction. Theory and evidence from the organisational behaviour literature suggest that, at the individual level, both of these traits are positively related to job performance. In a meta-analysis of 312 independent samples, Judge et al. (Reference Judge, Thoresen, Bono and Patton2001) found a correlation between job satisfaction and job performance of 0.30. Similarly, in a meta-analysis of 101 independent samples, Spector (Reference Spector1986) found a correlation between autonomy and job performance of 0.26. In fact, these correlations likely underestimate the total impact of job satisfaction and autonomy on performance, given that both are associated with numerous other work attitudes and behaviours that are themselves related to performance. These include, for instance, organisational commitment, role conflict, role ambiguity, emotional distress, absenteeism, turnover intention and actual turnover (Spector Reference Spector1986; Mathieu and Zajac Reference Mathieu and Zajac1990; Tett and Meyer Reference Tett and Meyer1993; Meyer et al. Reference Meyer, Stanley, Herscovitch and Topolnytsky2002; Riketta Reference Riketta2002).

Theories of public sector organisational effectiveness and political control pay special attention to autonomy. The former typically emphasises autonomy’s salutary operational qualities: it allows agencies to use their expertise to solve pressing implementation problems, make and execute decisions quickly, and pursue their missions in an administratively rational manner (see, e.g. Wilson Reference Wilson1989; Wolf Reference Wolf1993; Meier Reference Meier1997; Rainey and Steinbauer Reference Rainey and Steinbauer1999; Brewer and Selden Reference Brewer and Selden2000). These theories also assume that autonomy has motivational benefits at the employee level. Individuals – particularly individuals with high levels of formal education and professional training – value autonomy and work harder when it is given to them (see, e.g. Gagné and Deci Reference Gagné and Deci2005). In contrast, theories of political control tend to view autonomy as necessary – bureaucracies have expertise that political actors lack, and so delegations of authority are sometimes unavoidable – but potentially problematic, given that bureaucracies are nonelectoral institutions. Yet, even political theories note the importance of autonomy for organisational performance. Gailmard and Patty (Reference Gailmard and Patty2007, Reference Gailmard and Patty2012), for example, argue that congressional principals, who generally prefer informed to uninformed policymaking, proactively grant autonomy and policymaking discretion to bureaucratic agents in order to incentivise investments in expertise. Whatever their differences, both schools tend to agree that autonomy is systematically associated with organisational performance and the development of policy expertise. Consequently, we believe it is important to examine whether congressional oversight is associated with agency autonomy.

Congressional oversight and its managerial consequences

We expect that congressional oversight will be negatively associated with autonomy and job satisfaction when such oversight is primarily meant to monitor and control the bureaucracy for political reasons, rather than to aid it in the performance of agency duties (Weingast and Moran Reference Weingast and Moran1983; Ferejohn and Shipan Reference Ferejohn and Shipan1990; Shipan Reference Shipan2004). Congress is often unlike the manager or firm owner described in standard economic accounts of principal-agent theory. In these accounts, it is usually assumed that the principal is concerned with securing some outcome and is, moreover, happy to let the agent choose whatever means or behaviours best serve that end (for a review, see Eisenhardt Reference Eisenhardt1989). The congressional impulse to control, however, often seeks to dictate the bureaucracy’s choice of means. This impulse is intensified in our separation of powers system, where Congress often competes with the president for agency influence (Shapiro Reference Shapiro1994; Whitford Reference Whitford2005). Below, we identify three particular mechanisms through which congressional oversight can harm agency morale and conclude by arguing that oversight’s relationship with morale is ultimately conditional on whether it is adversarial or friendly.

Mechanism I: micromanagement

Consistent with the predilection of Congress to be interested in control rather than performance, scholars have long noted that its oversight relationship with the federal bureaucracy has been characterised by micromanagement, or “intervention by Congress in administrative details” (Gilmour and Halley Reference Gilmour and Halley1994, 10). As early as 1885, Woodrow Wilson complained that Congress “has entered more and more into the details of the administration, until it has virtually taken into its own hands all the substantial powers of government” (Wilson 1896, cited in Beermann 2006). Similarly, Wilson wrote that “Congress is commonly criticized for ‘micromanaging’ government agencies; it does and it always has” (Reference Wilson1989, 241). More recently, Behn identified political micromanagement as one of public administration’s most pressing problems and elucidated how it hampers agency performance: “The legislative branch is, for some reason, unhappy with the way an executive-branch agency is performing; so the legislators impose some rules on the agency … These new rules prevent, or at least constrain, the agency from doing what the legislature dislikes. Unfortunately, these rules also constrain the agency from producing the results for which it is responsible” (Reference Behn1995, 316).

There is reason to believe that oversight has become increasingly driven by this impulse to micromanage and constrain bureaucratic discretion. Summarising a series of 10 case studies on oversight, Gilmour and Halley concluded:

The cases show a “congressional co-manager” intervening directly in the details of policy development and management rather than enacting vague, wide-ranging, sweeping statutes to change fundamental policy directions …

Gone almost without a trace is the post-New Deal Congress that optimistically delegated broad-scale public problems and policy questions for solution and resolution by the executive branch. Much diminished as well is an executive branch relied upon by Congress for neutral competence and specialized expertise. Instead, the story … is one of the retrieval of executive discretion and the highly specific redefinition—by Congress—of prior delegations of authority. (Reference Gilmour and Halley1994, 335–336)

In the same vein, Aberbach (Reference Aberbach1990) showed that the average number of pages per statute enacted by Congress rose sharply between the 80th (1947–1948) and the 103rd (1993–1994) sessions of Congress, indicating an increased command-and-control orientation in legislative-bureaucratic relations. More recently, Balla and Deering (Reference Balla and Deering2013) coded a sample of all congressional hearings that occurred during the 96th (1979–1981), 100th (1987–1989), 104th (1995–1997) and 108th (2003–2004) sessions of Congress. They found that most hearings – over 80% in each session – are police patrols, as opposed to fire alarms, indicating that Congress has an abiding interest in monitoring what the federal bureaucracy is doing and in how it is doing it.

As a recent illustration of this mechanism, scholarly research and witness testimony from administrators from the Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services (CMS) attest that members of Congress are keen to micromanage policies governing provider payment (Pham et al. Reference Pham, Ginsburg and Verdier2009). The data that we compile below support these claims, indicating that there were no fewer than 377 oversight hearings from 1999 to 2013 where members of Congress expressed their views on this issue, often disagreeing with CMS policies. Representative of these interactions is a 15 May 2007 hearing of the House Committee on Ways and Means’s Subcommittee on Health, under the direction of subcommittee chairman Pete Stark (D-CA). In this hearing, titled “Payments to Certain Medicaid Fee-for-Service Providers”, Stark belies his intent to intervene in CMS regulations, upon “hearing from industry that many of these regulations, particularly the inpatient hospital regulations, are nothing but backdoor attempts to circumvent Congress and cut spending”. In addition, despite being “loathe to intervene in the nuts and bolts of regulations”, and generally thinking “that level of detail is best left to the experts like Mr. Kuhn [Herb Kuhn, then Acting Deputy Administrator, Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services]”, Congressman Stark felt impelled to give pages of suggestions on how CMS should direct fee-for-service payments to providers. Such intricate congressional involvement in agency decisions is common in our hearings data and an indication that more oversight often means more direct congressional involvement in policy implementation.

Micromanagement is fundamentally a psychological mechanism. It is harmful to agency morale because it politicises employees’ work and, in doing so, undermines employees’ ability to experience meaning while performing their jobs (Hackman and Oldham Reference Hackman and Oldham1976; Ryan and Deci Reference Ryan and Deci2000; Barrick et al. Reference Barrick, Mount and Li2013). A large body of research on “public service motivation” suggests that for many individuals who are employed in the public sector the experience of meaning flows from doing work that is thought to advance the public good (see, e.g. Perry and Wise Reference Perry and Wise1990; Houston Reference Houston2009). At its core, public service motivation is an “other-regarding” orientation; it entails a broad-based concern for the well-being of one’s fellow citizens, as opposed to a more narrow concern for particularistic interests (Ward Reference Ward2014). Micromanagement can hurt agency morale by appropriating an agency’s collective work effort for partisan purposes and, in doing so, stripping that effort of its politically neutral public service meaning. Just as a generic manager’s use of monetary rewards to incentivise employee effort can “crowd out”, or displace, an employee’s intrinsic motivation for doing a job well (Frey and Oberholzer-Gee Reference Frey and Oberholzer-Gee1997), congressional micromanagement can crowd out agency employees’ public service motivation by signalling to employees that their work is ultimately partisan in nature.

We view congressional micromanagement as a variable that shapes an agency’s shared understandings of, and collective beliefs about, the purpose of its core work. In other words, micromanagement affects agency morale via its influence on agency culture. In this view, an employee need not be directly exposed to congressional oversight for the micromanagement mechanism to be operative; the employee need only be exposed to the agency’s prevailing cultural beliefs. In agencies that are subject to a significant amount of politically motivated oversight, we would expect a “politicised” culture to obtain. In these agencies, employees would understand their work to be primarily partisan and would be demoralised by this understanding. In contrast, in agencies subject to little political oversight, we would expect a relatively “apolitical” culture to obtain. In these agencies, employees would understand their work to be primarily in service of the public good and would be heartened by this understanding.

Mechanism II: short term, recurring opportunity costs

Besides this micromanagement mechanism, there are at least two more possible avenues by which oversight may harm agency morale. First, preparing for and participating in oversight hearings, especially high-profile ones, levies opportunity costs on agency employees. Rather than focussing on, say, fulfilling their missions, or competently implementing legislative policy, agency employees must respond to the priorities of a committee holding an oversight hearing. We call these opportunity costs short term to differentiate them from the more fundamental (and psychological) crowding-out of experienced meaning that congressional micromanagement entails.

Short-term opportunity costs likely fall most squarely on agency managers, especially those who are called to testify in an oversight hearing. These employees must, quite literally, put down whatever they are working on to prepare for and attend a hearing. A recent journalistic account of declining morale among high-level agency managers at the Department of Homeland Security supports this line of reasoning. As the article notes, “Many former and current officials said the most burdensome part of working for DHS is the demands of congressional oversight. More than 90 committees and subcommittees have some jurisdiction over DHS, nearly three times the number that oversee the Defense Department. Preparing for the blizzard of hearings and briefings, officials say, leaves them less time to do their jobs” (Markon et al. Reference Markon, Nakashima and Crites2014).

While we assume that oversight hearings will produce higher opportunity costs for managerial than nonmanagerial employees, it is plausible that at least some of these costs will impinge on the daily work routines of an agency’s middle- and lower-level employees. Managers will likely need help preparing for and responding to hearings, and it is reasonable to expect that they will delegate some of their hearings-related work to nonmanagers. Yet, in terms of their impact on the felt autonomy and job satisfaction of nonmanagerial employees, we view short-term opportunity costs as secondary to micromanagement. Although micromanagement undermines the very meaning of work done by agency employees, opportunity costs are merely temporary (albeit perhaps frequent) disruptions to an employee’s work routine.Footnote 5

Mechanism III: public shaming

Finally, it is reasonable to assume that negative congressional attention whose aim is to publicly embarrass high-level agency managers would be demoralising to the agency as a whole. A recent example of this involves the General Services Administration (GSA) and the attention it received in 2012, after stories of wasteful spending at its Western Regions Conference surfaced in the media. The aftermath included many high-profile oversight hearings and numerous internal reports that sought to assign responsibility for the agency’s actions. As “fraud, waste and abuse” are anathema to both parties, Democrats as well as Republicans relentlessly attacked the GSA in hearings. In this instance, Congress can be seen to have had a genuine interest in improving GSA performance into the future. In other words, this was an ideal opportunity for Congress to act as a genuine performance manager – that is, to take a sincere interest in remedying whatever underlying organisational problems (e.g. issues with organisational culture, ineffective internal accountability structures, etc.) may have contributed to the GSA scandal. Instead, Congress appeared to be more interested in obtaining whatever political mileage it could by publicly scolding top-level GSA employees.

Of course, agency managers should be called to account for agency misbehaviour. Nevertheless, it is important to emphasise that public shaming is not viewed as a constructive managerial practice in the organisational behaviour and public management literatures. In fact, recent research suggests that “abusive supervision”, which includes “nonphysical actions such as angry outbursts, public ridiculing, taking credit for subordinates’ successes, and scapegoating subordinates”, is negatively associated with job satisfaction, turnover intention and additional markers of employee morale (Tepper Reference Tepper2000, Reference Tepper2007; Aryee et al. Reference Aryee, Chen, Sun and Debrah2007).Footnote 6 Importantly, research in this vein also indicates that the abusive supervision endured by an organisation’s higher-level employees “trickles down” to its lower-level employees (Aryee et al. Reference Aryee, Chen, Sun and Debrah2007). In this view, the supervisory treatment that high-level employees receive influences the manner in which they treat their own subordinates. Notwithstanding these potential trickle-down effects, we assume that public shaming is more strongly associated with managerial employees’ morale than nonmanagerial employees’ morale. Although the high-level managerial employees who attend hearings will endure any shaming attempts firsthand, nonmanagerial employees’ exposure will be indirect.

“Advocacy” and the conditional effects of oversight

Thus far, we have discussed three mechanisms via which oversight hearings may negatively affect agency morale. These mechanisms would seem to operate across qualitatively different types of oversight hearing. Police patrol oversight, for example, is most likely to reflect Congress’s desire to micromanage (Balla and Deering Reference Balla and Deering2013). These hearings also require diligent agency preparation and are likely to command persistent short-term opportunity costs. Fire alarm hearings (McCubbins and Schwartz Reference McCubbins and Schwartz1984) also require agency preparation, often on short notice, and thus we expect agencies to be burdened by high opportunity costs here as well. In addition, fire alarms are more likely to trigger particularly adversarial hearings, thus activating the public shaming mechanism.Footnote 7 In fact, all of these mechanisms rely on the assumption that oversight hearings are contentious affairs.

Yet, existing work (Aberbach Reference Aberbach1990) cautions us against making the assumption that all hearings serve the same purpose. Aberbach (Reference Aberbach1990), drawing on survey evidence from committee members and their staff, shows that much congressional oversight activity takes place in what he calls an “advocacy context”. Aberbach stresses that there are two general types of committee oversight: adversarial hearings meant to score political points or forcibly change agency policy (through micromanagement, as discussed above); and advocacy hearings, where members of Congress defend “their” preferred programmes and agencies by holding hearings and officially voicing praise and approval. This type of oversight is qualitatively different from that assumed in our theoretical discussion regarding the negative effects of hearings on agency morale. There is little reason to expect any of the three proposed mechanisms to drive down morale when committees are friendly towards agencies in hearings. In fact, we might even expect that advocacy hearings increase agency morale, as they publicly demonstrate agency accomplishments, and can serve to justify increased appropriations (Aberbach Reference Aberbach1990, Chapter 8). In addition, when Congress’s and the bureaucracy’s goals are aligned and oversight is positive and advocacy driven, it is conceivable that Congress might assume the salutary managerial role that is exalted in theories of public sector organisational effectiveness (O’Toole and Meier Reference O’Toole and Meier1999; Rainey and Steinbauer Reference Rainey and Steinbauer1999; Fernandez Reference Fernandez2005; Lee and Whitford Reference Lee and Whitford2013).

We ultimately argue that the relationship between congressional oversight activity and agency morale is a conditional one. When oversight is politically driven and adversarial, we expect it to harm agency morale, for the reasons discussed above. Yet, when oversight is more “friendly”, agencies can benefit, both tangibly and intangibly, from congressional attention. Although agencies still have to prepare for these hearings, the outcomes of these preparations (potential praise and material rewards) can often outweigh the short-term opportunity costs of hearing involvement. Thus, to the extent that oversight hearings are positive towards the target agency, we expect them to increase agency morale.

Data, variables and methods

In order to assess the conditional relationship between congressional oversight and agency morale, we first created empirical measures of each. We focussed exclusively on formal oversight hearings as, of the myriad forms of oversight,Footnote 8 these are the most straightforward to quantify and have been the focus of many empirical studies (Dodd and Schott Reference Dodd and Schott1979; Aberbach Reference Aberbach1990; Ogul and Rockman Reference Ogul and Rockman1990; Smith Reference Smith2003; Balla and Deering Reference Balla and Deering2013; McGrath Reference McGrath2013; MacDonald and McGrath forthcoming). Nevertheless, existing studies have not considered oversight as an agency-level demand-side variable, and have instead focussed almost entirely on the supply-side of oversight. The few studies that have considered oversight from an agency perspective have focussed on small samples of agencies or hearings and have not documented the overall extent to which agencies are called to appear before Congress (see, e.g. Parnell Reference Parnell1980; May et al. Reference May, Workman and Jones2008, Reference May, Sapotichne and Workman2009, Reference May, Jochim and Sapotichne2011). Therefore, we developed a unique measure of oversight hearings directed at federal agencies as our primary independent variable.

Oversight hearings data

We collected data on oversight hearings from the Government Printing Office’s Federal Digital System (GPO’s FDsys) (http://www.gpo.gov/fdsys/search/advanced/advsearchpage.action).Footnote 9 The GPO began publishing a sizable number of hearing transcripts in 1997; therefore, we started our collection there.Footnote 10 The description of the GPO’s hearings data indicates that committees sometimes take up to two years to publish hearings, and thus we attenuated our data set to conclude at the end of 2011.Footnote 11 We collected the universe of hearings by searching the “Congressional Hearings” database with an empty keyword field and saved each full-text transcript. Each transcript contains a list of witnesses called before Congress for the hearing, including their affiliation with federal agencies, when applicable. All told, we identified 17,572 hearings in these data. We parsed the text of each individual hearing transcript to create witness data and then narrowed the witnesses by whether or not they represented an agency. We considered a hearing to be directed at a particular agency only if the committee or subcommittee holding the hearing called a witness from that agency. There are often cases where there are no agency-affiliated witnesses for a given hearing and still others where an individual hearing applies to multiple, and sometimes many, agencies. Next, we attempted to identify hearings that were meant to conduct oversight and separate them from legislative hearings. As described in supplementary appendix A, we followed recent research (McGrath Reference McGrath2013; MacDonald and McGrath forthcoming) and filtered oversight hearings by searching the full-text transcripts for keywords that might indicate oversight.Footnote 12 After filtering, we identified a total of 11,407 oversight hearings in our data.

Once we identified agency witnesses and separated oversight from nonoversight hearings, we grouped hearings by agency and year. The agency-year data set then had 1,053 observations – 13 full years of data for 80 agencies and two agencies with fewer than 13 observations because of being created after 1999.Footnote 13 The agencies were grouped by the coding scheme for the 2012 Federal Human Capital Survey so as to allow us to match the hearings data to the agency morale data described below. Generally speaking, the data are grouped at the department level, including independent agencies and the Office of Management and Budget (part of the Executive Office of the President), with some departmental subunits included.Footnote 14

Supplementary Table A1 (appendix A) indicates each agency for which we have collected hearings data and gives descriptive statistics for such oversight activity. Figure 1 displays how the total number of oversight hearings committees held across the 82 coded agencies varies over time. The data cover a time period that was characterised by the full diversity of institutional and partisan configurations – namely, we have been through unified government, divided government with a unified Congress, divided government with a divided Congress, Republican presidents, Democratic presidents and changes in the partisan control of each chamber during this period. Figure 2 displays temporal changes in oversight hearings across the 15 cabinet-level departments, further demonstrating the variation that exists in these data. In addition, Figure 3 shows, via box plots, the distributions of oversight hearings for each department. Although obviously crucial for testing how oversight can affect agency morale, these data are inherently interesting in demonstrating the significant variation that exists in how often certain agencies are called to appear before Congress, and future research should model this variation as an outcome, as well as a determinant of agency characteristics (MacDonald and Reference MacDonald and McGrathMcGrath forthcoming).

Figure 1 Oversight hearing days (1999–2011)Note: Figure created by summing all oversight hearing days for all agencies in a given year. Hearings can involve more than one agency at a time, so this can result in double-counting hearings. We show this double-counted measure of hearings activity as it more accurately captures total agency attention to congressional priorities.

Figure 2 Oversight hearings over time by department

Figure 3 Distribution of oversight hearings by departmentNote: Horizontal lines give the median for each agency, boxes give the bounds of the interquartile range and dots show outliers.

Measuring hearing sentiment

As we have argued above, the effects of oversight on morale should depend on the fundamental tone and purpose of the hearings. As such, we additionally analysed the content of each hearing to categorise it as either adversarial or advocacy driven. Adversarial hearings reflect what most observers think of when they consider oversight. Here, members of congressional committees call agencies to task for poor performance, or simply for implementing policy inimical to the wishes of a committee. These hearings are often acerbic affairs, and are unpleasant experiences for agency employees called to testify. They additionally require agencies to prepare extensive reports and testimony to avoid public embarrassment. These are the hearings that we expect to negatively affect agency morale.

On the other hand, Aberbach described an alternative to adversarial hearings: “While one’s first reaction to the word ‘oversight’ is that Congress is at odds with an agency or program targeted, committees sometimes use oversight because they want to defend ‘their’ program or agency against others who would do it harm” (Reference Aberbach1990, 118). This brand of advocacy oversight has been largely overlooked by empirical studies, although there is evidence that this makes up a good part of Congress’s oversight agenda, especially during unified government (see Aberbach Reference Aberbach1990, Chapter 8). We do not expect such hearings to negatively affect agency morale; rather, we expect that when hearings are positive in tone, they will actually improve agency morale.

We thus seek to categorise congressional oversight as either adversarial or friendly, and we do so by measuring hearing sentiment. Specifically, we undertake computer-assisted sentiment analyses of each hearing, following standard practice in the computer science literature and a growing trend in the social sciences.Footnote 15 Hearing transcripts follow a fairly standard format. They open with metadata about the hearing (those in attendance, the time and location of the meeting, a list of witnesses, etc.), and then invariably commence with the opening statements of the committee or subcommittee chair and other interested members of Congress. These opening statements are the primary source of our sentiment data, as they provide many instances where a member of Congress expresses sentiment towards an agency.

For each observation in the agency-hearing data set described above and in supplementary appendix A, we calculated a Targeted Sentiment score that we used to measure how positive (positive values to 1) or negative (negative values to −1) each hearing is with respect to the agency at hand.Footnote 16 There is a good deal of variation in sentiment scores across the data, with a mean score of 0.068 and a SD of 0.278 (empirical range: −0.901 to 0.925). As our data are organised at the agency-year level, we aggregated from individual hearings by taking the mean sentiment for each agency and year (Hearings Sentiment). We assessed our conditional hypotheses below by interacting this overall measure of oversight sentiment with the total volume of oversight hearings conducted involving each agency in each year.

Measuring agency morale

Viewing agency morale as a set of characteristics best discerned from individual responses to surveys of federal employees, we adopted the approach of Bertelli et al. (Reference Bertelli, Mason, Connolly and Gastwirth2015) of measuring agency-level characteristics by aggregating these individual responses. This approach builds on earlier attempts to use individual employee attitudes to approximate unobservable agency characteristics,Footnote 17 and seeks to overcome some of the limitations of these types of data. In particular, Bertelli et al. (Reference Bertelli, Mason, Connolly and Gastwirth2015) provided a framework for aggregating survey responses in such a way as to put agency-level summaries on a common scale for cross-agency and overtime comparisons. Such an approach is key for our endeavour to test the effects of oversight activity on agency morale in a panel data setup. Having consecutive years of data on oversight and agency morale across agencies thus allows us to use a fixed effects design, isolating the within-agency effects of changes in oversight activity on self-reported agency characteristics.

Bertelli et al. (Reference Bertelli, Mason, Connolly and Gastwirth2015) started by identifying the agency characteristics they wished to measure: autonomy, job satisfaction and intrinsic motivation. They considered these characteristics to be latent attributes and used individual responses to particular questions from federal personnel surveys to measure these constructs using a dynamic Bayesian item-response model similar to the approach in Martin and Quinn (Reference Martin and Quinn2002) (see also, Clinton et al. Reference Clinton, Jackman and Rivers2004, Reference Clinton, Bertelli, Grose, Lewis and Nixon2012; Bertelli and Grose Reference Bertelli and Grose2011).Footnote 18

Of these measured agency-level characteristics, we focussed particularly on agency autonomy and job satisfaction as constructs that relate to agency “morale” as a meta-characteristic of interest. Bertelli et al. (Reference Bertelli, Mason, Connolly and Gastwirth2015), among other studies, did not necessarily equate autonomy with the possession of objectively large amounts of statutory administrative discretion (Epstein and O’Halloran Reference Epstein and O’Halloran1999; Huber and Shipan Reference Huber and Shipan2002). Instead, autonomy refers to the extent to which bureaucrats feel in control of their own surroundings in performing their duties: a more subjective sense of discretion. The job satisfaction variable is what organisational behaviour researchers typically call a “global” measure – that is, a measure of overall job satisfaction. Each of the three survey items that together constitute this measure encourage respondents to think in very broad terms about their jobs. One of the items asks, for instance, “Considering everything, how satisfied are you with your job?”.Footnote 19

Figure 4 displays the autonomy measures and the variation that exists in each across the cabinet departments, as Figure 5 does for the measure of job satisfaction.Footnote 20

Figure 4 Agency autonomy by department

Figure 5 Job satisfaction by department

Empirical strategy

Having collected panel dataFootnote 21 on levels of oversight and agency morale characteristics, with each measure varying considerably over time (again, see Figure 2, 4 and 5), we turn now to identifying the most appropriate empirical design by which to assess the relationship between oversight and morale. We are primarily interested in the effect that changes in oversight might have on agency morale over time. Ideally, we would like to tease out temporally causal relationships from confounded, spurious or endogenous correlations and have chosen a design and model specifications that we believe will help us get there. In particular, we take advantage of our data structure to estimate fixed effects models, thus accounting for unobserved agency heterogeneity and isolating the effects of time-varying covariates on time-varying agency characteristics.

Yet, this design does not erase the potential for biased estimates, nor does it guarantee casual interpretations of these estimates. In particular, we are careful to measure and account for factors that might simultaneously cause increases in oversight activity and changes in autonomy and job satisfaction, respectively. Our primary explanatory variable, Oversight Hearings, varies both across and within agencies over time, and our research is designed to isolate the effects of within-agency across-time changes in oversight on expressed agency traits. Therefore, we limited our attention to control variables that similarly vary within agencies over time, as the fixed effects eliminate all sources of time-invariant agency heterogeneity, observed and unobservable.

News sentiment and other controls

Perhaps, most importantly, we controlled for the possibility that something, such as an agency scandal of the sort described above with respect to the GSA, contributes both to the variation in Oversight Hearings and to the measures of agency morale. Agency scandals and aggregations of smaller issues related to poor agency performance invariably lead to “fire alarm” oversight by congressional committees eager to show constituents how they can fix agency problems (McCubbins and Schwartz Reference McCubbins and Schwartz1984). Scandals and poor performance also generate negative media attention that presumably has deleterious effects on agency morale, independent of the potential effects of the hearings themselves. It is thus necessary to disentangle the effects of negative media attention from the effects of congressional oversight.Footnote 22

To this end, we created a measure of media attention by collecting all stories published in the Washington Post that mentioned each agency in our data set.Footnote 23 We grouped the stories by agency and year and calculated the total number of stories and pages of coverage. This approach is similar to recent attempts to measure mass media attention to federal agencies (Lee et al. Reference Lee, Rainey and Chun2009; Lee and Whitford Reference Lee and Whitford2013), but we must also take into account the sentiment that these aggregated stories reflect towards agencies. Therefore, exactly as we did with the hearing transcripts, we measured the targeted sentiment of each news article in these data to create News Sentiment scores reflecting how positive (positive values to 1) or negative (negative values to −1) each piece of coverage is with respect to the agency at hand. We then calculated the sum of News Sentiment scores for each agency-year and used this as our measure, Total Washington Post Sentiment, capturing both the amount and direction of news coverage of the agencies in our data.

We also accounted for political attention to agencies, apart from the attention that oversight hearings themselves indicate. First, we separately included the volume of Nonoversight Hearings for each agency-year into our models. These are the hearings that we collected from the GPO that did not include the keywords we considered to indicate oversight.Footnote 24 Likewise, we recognised that agencies may be the recipients of other kinds of political attention that may affect employees’ responses to survey questions. As in the study by Lee and Whitford (Reference Lee and Whitford2013), we operationalised a Presidential Attention variable, using the GPO’s FDsys to search for mentions of each agency in the Public Papers of the Presidents of the United States.Footnote 25 Whitford (Reference Lee and Whitford2013) argued specifically that presidential attention might signal that political resources (time and money) are available for agency policy priorities.

In addition to these measures of media and political attention, we included indicators for various regimes of political control. Although we are mostly agnostic about the potential effects of these variables on changes in agency morale, we know that they are important determinants of congressional delegation to agencies in the first place (see, e.g. Kiewiet and McCubbins Reference Kiewiet and McCubbins1991; Epstein and O’Halloran Reference Epstein and O’Halloran1996; Huber and Shipan Reference Huber and Shipan2002; Volden Reference Volden2002) and of congressional incentives to hold hearings with or investigate agencies (see, e.g. Mayhew Reference Mayhew2005; Kriner and Schwartz Reference Kriner and Schwartz2008; Parker and Dull Reference Parker and Dull2009; McGrath Reference McGrath2013). These variables include an indicator for Divided Government, and one each for Republican Control of Congress, Democratic President and Presidential Transition Year.

Notably, we did not include any time-invariant agency characteristics, as they would present identification issues in a fixed effects setup. This ultimately means that we cannot directly assess which specific mechanisms are at play in generating the relationships that we find. Although these mechanisms have distinct observable implications, these are found in agency-level characteristics and unmeasured characteristics of the hearings. For example, we argued above that public shaming can cascade from those managers who were involved in an oversight hearing to agency careerists. This mechanism might imply that such cascades should have larger impacts on agency morale in small, tight-knit agencies. Yet, agency size is largely time-invariant, and is thus collinear with agency fixed effects.Footnote 26 Indeed, these agency fixed effects are crucial for us to make reliable estimates of the relationships between oversight and morale, as agency characteristics (e.g. size, budget, political insulation) are so often correlated with each other and with congressional attention. We thus limit our current attention to uncovering reliable estimates, net of the effects of agency-level characteristics, and leave the subtle task of mechanism assessment to future research.Footnote 27

We should also note that we have some ex ante concerns regarding endogeneity. Specifically, it might be the case that instead of oversight activity affecting agency morale, the relationship is the inverse, with congressional committees choosing to hold hearings with agencies with particular latent characteristics, such as high or low autonomy. We took a number of steps to ameliorate this inferential pitfall. First, we lagged the hearings covariates by one year. There is little reason to expect a contemporaneous and swift reaction in the autonomy or job satisfaction dependent variables to a change in hearings activity. Instead, by lagging each of the hearings variables, we can assess what we see as a more realistic temporal ordering, where the effects of hearings in period t−1 take until the survey in period t to be reflected in the measured agency traits.Footnote 28 Next, we have specified each dependent variable as the one-time period change in agency autonomy and job satisfaction from time t−1 to time t. As plausible as it is to consider oversight and morale being endogenously related, it is less worrisome to consider the unlikely scenario that Congress oversees agencies with especially high (or low) changes from year to year in autonomy (or job satisfaction). For these reasons, we have both lagged the primarily important hearings independent variables and created differenced change in autonomy and job satisfaction dependent variables.

In addition, we have modelled remaining endogeneity directly with an instrumental variables approach (see, e.g. Angrist and Krueger Reference Angrist and Krueger2001; Wooldridge Reference Wooldridge2010). Generally, for instrumental variables regression to solve endogeneity problems, one must find an IV that is strongly correlated with the endogenous regressor (Oversight Hearings), but not directly related to the outcome variable (Agency Autonomy/Job Satisfaction). We have identified two such instruments, Second Session of a Congress and Presidential Election Year, both of which drive down congressional oversight, but show no direct correlation with our dependent variables. Inclusion of these instruments and estimation of two-stage least squares regression does not change any of our substantive interpretations, lessening our concerns regarding endogeneity.Footnote 29

Results

Table 1 displays results for both dependent variables. For each column, we have included all of the control variables described above, as well as agency fixed effects, and additional fixed effects for each year in the time series to account for systematic heterogeneity across time.Footnote 30

Table 1 Ordinary least squares models of agency autonomy and job satisfaction (1999–2011)

Note: Entries are linear regression coefficient estimates and standard errors, clustered by agency. The dependent variables are created by calculating the change in the Bertelli et al. (Reference Bertelli, Mason, Connolly and Gastwirth2015) measures of autonomy and job satisfaction (excluding compensation questions) from time t−1 to time t. Agency and year fixed effects (FE) are included in all models but not reported. See supplementary appendix A for further description of the oversight data, supplementary appendix C for more information on the hearings sentiment scores and supplementary appendix D for a description of the Washington Post sentiment scores.

AIC=Akaike’s information criterion; BIC=Bayesian information criterion.

*p<0.10, **p<0.05, ***p<0.01.

In columns 1 and 2, we purposefully begin with a naive model specification. In these columns, we exclude information regarding hearing sentiment and assess the unconditional relationships between Oversight Hearings and the Change in Autonomy and Change in Job Satisfaction dependent variables. Estimating this unconditional relationship serves to highlight the importance of the models found in columns 3 and 4, where we empirically distinguish between adversarial and more friendly oversight. These unconditional results demonstrate that increases in lagged Oversight Hearings are associated with decreases in both autonomy and job satisfaction. Both of these effects are statistically distinguishable from 0 and are relatively substantial in their magnitude. In contrast, only one of the control variables across these first two models is statistically significant (Nonoversight Hearings in column 2).

Columns 3 and 4 introduce our operationalisation of the conditionality implied by theory. Although the results from columns 1 and 2 indicate that increased oversight activity leads to decreased agency autonomy and job satisfaction, we suspect that this is the case due to the distributions of adversarial and advocacy oversight hearings, with the former more likely to occur than the latter in the time period being studied. To assess this explanation, and to evaluate how oversight’s effect on agency morale depends on the content of the oversight attention it receives, we included our measure of Hearings Sentiment. As described above and in supplementary appendix B, we measured a sentiment score [ranging from most negative (−1) to most positive (+1)] for each agency hearing in the data. We then calculated the mean values of all of the hearings involving an agency as a global approximation of how negatively or positively Congress has interacted with each agency in each year (the mean of this variable for the estimation sample is 0.03, with a SD of 0.15 and an empirical range from −0.52 to 0.84). We then interacted the lagged values of this hearings sentiment measure with the lagged number of Oversight Hearings involving each agency in each year to capture the intensity, as well as the direction, of agency-congressional interactions.

Column 3 presents results for Change in Autonomy when we added the interaction of Oversight Hearings and Hearings Sentiment to the specification from column 1. Here, the constitutive term for Oversight Hearings tells us that the effect of additional oversight hearings when the mean sentiment of hearings towards an agency are neutral (sentiment score of 0) is negative and statistically significant. Alternatively, we can approximately interpret this as meaning that the marginal effect of additional neutral oversight hearings is significantly negative, indicating that at least one of the mechanisms discussed above is at work even when hearings are not expressly negative in tone. The interaction term, on the other hand, indicates that as hearings become more positive, the effect of oversight on autonomy reverses and becomes statistically significantly positive at a Hearings Sentiment score around 0.50. These very positive hearings likely constitute what Aberbach calls “advocacy” oversight, and when agencies see more of this type of oversight it tends to increase feelings of autonomy. As such extremely positive hearings are relatively rare in the data, this conditional relationship is obscured when we look at the results from columns 1 and 2. On the other hand, the results demonstrate that extremely negative hearings are even more likely to reduce agency autonomy than neutral hearings. To illustrate, the marginal effect of increases in hearing activity for neutral hearings (sentiment score of 0) is −0.002, which more than triples for more negative hearings (sentiment score of −0.25 has a marginal effect of −0.007) and increases all the way to −0.011 for the most negative hearings in the data (sentiment score of −0.52). Thus, we have evidence that feelings of agency autonomy respond not only to the volume of activity but also to the degree of negativity (or positivity) they express.

These results are substantively meaningful. Consider the distribution of the Change in Autonomy dependent variable – mean: −0.0085, SD: 0.34 and range: −1.05 to 0.925. When hearings are commonly negative (say, a standard deviation below the mean of Hearings Sentiment: a sentiment score of −0.12), it would take about 80 such hearings to lead to a standard deviation decrease in agency autonomy. On the other hand, if these hearings each carried a strongly positive sentiment (say, a sentiment score of 0.50), these 80 hearings would lead to an increase in agency autonomy of 0.045, which is significantly larger than the variable’s standard deviation. Although large increases in oversight are relatively rare (see Figure 2 and supplementary table A1 for more information on the distribution of the variable across agencies and over time), certain agencies do see relatively large changes in oversight over time. The Department of Defense, for example, increases from a minimum of 23 to a maximum of 129 in the data. In addition, focussing solely on the coefficient estimates and their marginal effects alone may obscure the importance of oversight. A change in oversight may lead to only a small change in autonomy, but that shifts the baseline for the next period, where more oversight can further decrease (or increase, if the tone of the hearings are positive) autonomy. The dynamics of the oversight-autonomy relationship thus allows us to treat the one period effect as a floor for the true substantive impact of oversight activity.

In Table 1, column 4 displays results for the same specification just described, but this time for the Change in Job Satisfaction dependent variable. Here, we see the same pattern of results as in column 4. Specifically, neutral and adversarial hearings tend to decrease aggregate (overall) job satisfaction within an agency, whereas more friendly hearings engender increases in such job satisfaction. Despite the statistical significance of the coefficient on the interaction term, the marginal effect for increases in friendly oversight is only marginally statistically significant, and only for the most positive hearings (sentiment scores of 0.65 or greater; compared with a 0.50 threshold for the Change in Autonomy dependent variable). Despite the smaller coefficients and effect magnitudes, we can make similar substantive interpretations of these results, as Change in Job Satisfaction has a smaller standard deviation (0.25) than does Change in Autonomy (0.45). In addition, across columns 3 and 4, the oversight and sentiment variables are the only factors that consistently affect agency measures of morale, suggesting that future studies of the determinants of morale, especially those using the Bertelli et al. (Reference Bertelli, Mason, Connolly and Gastwirth2015) approach, should at least control for oversight in their empirical models.

Conclusion

As a manager of the federal bureaucracy, Congress gets mixed reviews. On one hand, when it engages in friendly oversight, it bolsters agency morale. On the other, when it engages in adversarial oversight, it undermines agency morale. Some of the time, then, it appears to assume the salutary managerial role that is exalted in theories of public sector organisational effectiveness (O’Toole and Meier Reference O’Toole and Meier1999; Rainey and Steinbauer Reference Rainey and Steinbauer1999; Fernandez Reference Fernandez2005; Lee and Whitford Reference Lee and Whitford2013). At other times, it appears to be more interested in micromanaging and publicly shaming agencies than in abetting their performance. Although it is of course Congress’s prerogative to oversee the federal bureaucracy in the manner of its choosing, our results suggest that its interactions with agencies have concrete consequences for employee motivation. It strikes us reasonable that Congress should at least consider these consequences as it exercises its oversight function.

Quite simply, there is a balancing act that Congress should perform when considering oversight, and to truly understand it scholars need to assess the managerial consequences of oversight as well as its causes. Oversight may indeed be an effective mechanism for ensuring that agencies are responsive to the policy preferences of committee majorities (Kriner and Schickler Reference Kriner and Schickler2013; McGrath Reference McGrath2013; MacDonald and McGrath forthcoming), but the congressional desire to monitor and control the bureaucracy should be balanced against adversarial oversight’s likely detrimental effects on agency morale and, ultimately, agency performance. Our results suggest that “micromanagement” is more than a mere theoretical possibility. Apart from losing the benefits of delegation (expertise, insulation, etc.), Congress risks harming agency morale when it too vigorously monitors its agents. This should especially be concerning for a particular flavour of “show-horse” oversight that lacks policy content and is instead motivated by the desire to embarrass political opponents. Yet, it is also problematic in policy areas where technical expertise is required and political incentives align to meddle with policy details, as in the Medicare example above.Footnote 31

Ours is the first study to examine the relationship between oversight activity and latent agency characteristics, but it should not be considered the last word on the topic. We admit to a number of specific drawbacks of this study, as currently constructed. First, we do not directly measure agency performance. Instead, we focus on publicly available data on agency autonomy and job satisfaction as precursors to performance. Second, although we have proposed three theoretical mechanisms via which adversarial oversight negatively affects agency morale, our analyses cannot distinguish between these mechanisms. We envision progress on this front occurring as existing approaches to textual analysis are refined. Ultimately, we hope to be able to distinguish adversarial oversight hearings in which Congress is micromanaging from adversarial hearings in which Congress is simply shaming an agency. At the same time, we hope to be able to distinguish friendly oversight hearings in which Congress is genuinely engaged in the role of a performance manager from friendly hearings in which Congress is simply patting an agency on the back. When genuinely engaged, we would expect Congress to express commitment to a clear mission, to be attentive to agency exigencies, to allocate resources when necessary and to buffer agencies from the demands of the external environment (e.g. from the demands of particularistic interest groups). Knowing with a greater degree of precision what sort of oversight is actually happening during a hearing will allow scholars to pin down the theoretical mechanism (or mechanisms) via which oversight operates on agency attitudes and behaviour.

Up to now, empirical research has largely ignored the potential managerial consequences, both positive and negative, of congressional oversight. In particular, oversight’s negative managerial consequences have long been a cause for concern in the public administration and management literatures. At the same time, the political science literature evinces a deep concern for democratic accountability and its theoretical guarantor – political control. We have sought to synthesise these two perspectives and feel that we have identified an area where more research could lead to better agency performance on the ground. Our research speaks to classic debates concerning the politics-administration dichotomy and identifies a tangible consequence of the increase in oversight activity that has recently attracted much attention. Yet, a great deal remains to be done regarding empirical assessments of the consequences of congressional oversight.

Acknowledgements

A previous version of this paper was presented at the 2014 Annual Meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association, 3–6 April 2014, Chicago, IL. The authors thank Christopher Michael Carrigan, George Krause and numerous workshop participants from George Mason University’s School of Policy, Government and International Affairs for providing useful feedback. The authors also thank Henry Siegel, Lauren Gallagher, Fatima Arif, Betsy Cliff and Erica Liao for research assistance on this project.

Supplementary Material

To view supplementary material for this article, please visit http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0143814X15000367

Footnotes

1 Although we argue that morale is related to organisational performance, we are careful not to conflate the two concepts. Indeed, we expect to see future research make more direct assessments of the relationship between congressional oversight and agency performance.

2 Or selection of a “representative bureaucracy” (e.g. Meier Reference Meier1975; Meier and Nigro Reference Meier and Nigro1976).

3 We recognise that Congress is not, strictly speaking, the “boss” of the federal bureaucracy. Yet, we use workplace terminology as a metaphor for the principal-agent relationship that is said to exist between Congress and the bureaucracy (Miller Reference Miller2005). In addition, Congress is hardly an agency’s only boss (Whitford Reference Whitford2005; Gailmard Reference Gailmard2009), yet we would argue that the existence of multiple principals actually attenuates the empirical results we find below.

4 That congressional oversight is primarily determined by political and policy motivations is well established in the political science literature (see, e.g. Dodd and Schott Reference Dodd and Schott1979; Aberbach Reference Aberbach1990; Kriner and Schwartz Reference Kriner and Schwartz2008; Parker and Dull Reference Parker and Dull2009; Kriner and Schickler Reference Kriner and Schickler2013; McGrath Reference McGrath2013).

5 We do not separate managers from nonmanagers in our empirical analyses below, as this would limit the number of agencies for which we had enough managers to calculate aggregate morale. If managers are more negatively influenced by congressional oversight than nonmanagers, the large presence of nonmanagers in our data would bias our coefficients downward, making our estimates conservative.

6 In their account of declining morale at the Department of Homeland Security, Markon et al. (Reference Markon, Nakashima and Crites2014) identify “relentless congressional carping” as a source of employee unhappiness.

7 In the empirical analyses that follow, we are largely agnostic as to the mechanism driving the findings, and suspect that all three are at work across the heterogeneous sample of hearings and agencies in our data set.

8 There are many ways in which legislatures can review, monitor and supervise executive action. Committee members may engage in personal communication (even when this communication is technically illegal as “ex parte” communication) with bureaucratic staff or agency heads. Committee staff may also engage in such casework on behalf of their constituents. Besides committees, inspectors general reports (Light Reference Light1993), General Accounting Office reports and resolutions of enquiry (Oleszek Reference Oleszek2001) can serve to supplement the formal oversight work that committees engage in through hearings.

9 Smith (Reference Smith2003), McGrath (Reference McGrath2013) and MacDonald and McGrath (Reference MacDonald and McGrathforthcoming) used hearings data from the Policy Agendas Project’s (www.policyagendas.org) Congressional Hearings database (http://www.utexas.edu/cola/_webservices/policyagendas/ch/instances.csv?from=1945&to=2012) to construct summaries of oversight activity. Designed to capture congressional behaviour, this data source fails to indicate any agency information for the identified hearings. That is, although one can measure how often each committee or subcommittee of Congress met with agency personnel in a formal hearing, the Policy Agendas Project does not allow us to recover which agency is being scrutinised in each hearing.

10 We found hearings from 1993 to 1996 in the FDsys, but these constitute far less than a universe of committee hearings in those years. In addition, we limit our sample by ignoring data from 1997 to 1999, as the number of hearings identified in the GPO data for those years is far fewer than the number recorded in the Policy Agendas Project data.

11 The GPO further reports (http://www.gpo.gov/fdsys/browse/collection.action?collectionCode=CHRG) that “Not all congressional hearings are available on FDsys. Whether or not a hearing is disseminated on FDsys depends on the committee. GPO continues to add hearings as they become available during each session of Congress. If a congressional hearing is not listed in FDsys, it is not available electronically via GPO at this time. NOTE: If a committee has not made a hearing available electronically via GPO for a specific Congress, the committee’s name will not appear in the browse list until a hearing for that committee is made available in FDsys”. Although this is a worrying disclosure, each standing committee with oversight jurisdiction published hearings through the GPO in all years of the data. In addition, as mentioned above, the hearings published via the GPO closely track those identified in the Policy Agendas Project from 1999 to 2004 (the end year of complete data in that data set). In short, missing hearings data may be a problem, but there is no way to confirm the extent to which it is, or to correct for such missing data. We are confident that we have collected the universe of publicly available hearings data from 1999 to 2011.

12 These keywords are as follows: “oversight”, “investigation” and “budget request”.

13 For this article, we focus on subsets of these agencies where data on agency morale are currently available, as described below and further in supplementary appendix A.

14 For example, the US Air Force, Army and Navy are treated discretely apart from their parent Department of Defense.

15 See, e.g. Hopkins and King (2010) and Grimmer and Stewart (2013) for overviews and applications for political science. The basic idea is that articles, tweets, posts, hearings, etc. express positive, negative or neutral sentiments and that we can uncover and estimate these sentiments using statistical models.

16 As opposed to calculating the sentiment of the entire hearing, our scores measure sentiment directed towards a particular agency, denoted by the presence of the agency’s name in each transcript. We use a general algorithm to calculate sentiment scores and describe our process and the algorithm in more detail in supplementary appendix B.

17 See Bertelli et al. (Reference Bertelli, Mason, Connolly and Gastwirth2015) for a brief review of these studies.

18 See supplementary appendix C for a description of these data sources and a list of the questions and the surveys from which they were drawn. For more information on the aggregation and estimation procedures, see Bertelli et al. (Reference Bertelli, Mason, Connolly and Gastwirth2015).

19 In contrast, “facet” measures of job satisfaction are comprised of survey items that refer to specific aspects of an individual’s job, such as satisfaction with one’s coworkers, satisfaction with one’s opportunities for career advancement or satisfaction with one’s pay. We use a global measure of job satisfaction because meta-analytic evidence suggests that global measures are stronger predictors of job performance than are facet measures (see Judge et al. Reference Judge, Thoresen, Bono and Patton2001).

20 These are the summary measures found at http://agencydata.wordpress.com. They are bounded at −5 and 5.

21 The panel is unbalanced, as some agencies are missing data on key variables in some years. See supplementary appendices A and C for more information regarding missingness in the data.

22 Fire alarms may also spur court action, as federal courts have vast jurisdiction over federal agency policymaking and have the power to overturn agency decisions. Such court action might simultaneously affect agency morale and drive oversight activity, and, although it would be best if future research could directly measure and incorporate judicial attention, we rely on the likely correlation of such attention with the media attention variable we create below to assuage our concern that is a threat to inference.

23 We accessed the stories using the Lexis Nexis Academic database. We chose to explore Washington Post stories, in particular, because this newspaper dedicates more of its coverage to the federal bureaucracy than other national news organisations such as the New York Times. See supplementary appendix D for more detailed coding information.

24 The bulk of these nonoversight hearings concern prospective legislation, where agency testimony is used by a congressional committee to inform their policy decisions.

25 http://www.gpo.gov/fdsys/search/advanced/advsearchpage.action. We did the same with the Congressional Record for a measure of Congressional Attention, apart from attention through hearings. Yet, with agency fixed effects, we are limited in the number of covariates that we can include in a single model and this variable proved highly correlated (Pearson’s r of 0.67) with our measure of Oversight Hearings.

26 We have included some slowly changing agency-level variables such as agency size, budget and percentage of employees who are appointed, but they do not add to model fit or change the substantive interpretations we present.

27 Our data are not particularly amenable to testing mechanisms, so future research should focus on establishing the microfoundations of our theory by examining individual survey data, rather than aggregating to the agency level.

28 We lagged the Total Washington Post Sentiment and Hearings Sentiment variables for the same reasons.

29 For ease of interpretation, and as the results are largely identical across specifications, we present the standard regression results below, but present the second-stage instrumental variables results in supplementary appendix table E1.

30 We also cluster all standard errors by agency to allow for agency-specific trends in the error term. This has the effect of increasing the standard errors and makes finding statistical significance more difficult.

31 In fact, Congress itself has recognised the problem with this type of micromanagement and has sought to remedy its own proclivities. To wit, the 2010 Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act created an Independent Payment Advisory Board that has the ability to change payment schedules without previous congressional approval (although these decisions are subject to a supermajoritarian congressional veto).

References

Aberbach, J. D. (1990) Keeping a Watchful Eye: The Politics of Congressional Oversight. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.Google Scholar
Angrist, J. D. and Krueger, A. B. (2001) Instrumental Variables and the Search for Identification: From Supply and Demand to Natural Experiments. The Journal of Economic Perspectives 15(4): 6985.Google Scholar
Aryee, S., Chen, Z. X., Sun, L.-Y. and Debrah, Y. A. (2007) Antecedents and Outcomes of Abusive Supervision: Test of a Trickle-Down Model. Journal of Applied Psychology 92(1): 191201.Google Scholar
Balla, S. J. (1998) Administrative Procedures and Political Control of the Bureaucracy. The American Political Science Review 92(3): 663673.Google Scholar
Balla, S. J. and Deering, C. J. (2013) Police Patrol and Fire Alarms: An Empirical Examination of the Legislative Preference for Oversight. Congress & the Presidency 40(1): 2740.Google Scholar
Barrick, M. R., Mount, M. K. and Li, N. (2013) The Theory of Purposeful Work Behavior: The Role of Personality, Higher-Order Goals, and Job Characteristics. Academy of Management Review 38(1): 132153.Google Scholar
Beermann, J. M. (2006) Congressional Administration. San Diego Law Review 43(1): 61159.Google Scholar
Behn, R. D. (1995) The Big Questions of Public Management. Public Administration Review 55(4): 313324.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bendor, J., Taylor, S. and Van Gaalen, R. (1985) Bureaucratic Expertise Versus Legislative Authority: A Model of Deception and Monitoring in Budgeting. American Political Science Review 79(4): 10411060.Google Scholar
Bertelli, A. M. and Grose, C. R. (2011) The Lengthened Shadow of Another Institution: Ideal Point Estimates for the Executive Branch and Congress. American Journal of Political Science 55: 767781.Google Scholar
Bertelli, A. M., Mason, D. P., Connolly, J. M. and Gastwirth, D. A. (2015) Measuring Agency Attributes with Attitudes Across Time: A Method and Examples Using Large-Scale Federal Surveys. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 25(2): 513544.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brewer, G. A. and Selden, S. C. (2000) Why Elephants Gallop: Assessing and Predicting Organizational Performance in Federal Agencies. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 10(4): 685712.Google Scholar
Clinton, J. D., Bertelli, A., Grose, C., Lewis, D. E. and Nixon, D. C. (2012) Separated Powers in the United States: The Ideology of Agencies, Presidents, and Congress. American Journal of Political Science 56(2): 341354.Google Scholar
Clinton, J. D., Jackman, S. and Rivers, D. (2004) The Statistical Analysis of Roll Call Data. The American Political Science Review 98(2): 355370.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dodd, L. C. and Schott, R. L. (1979) Congress and the Administrative State. New York, NY: John Wiley & Sons.Google Scholar
Eisenhardt, K. M. (1989) Agency Theory: An Assessment and Review. Academy of Management Review 14(1): 5774.Google Scholar
Epstein, D. and O’Halloran, S. (1996) Divided Government and the Design of Administrative Procedures: A Formal Model and Empirical Test. The Journal of Politics 58(2): 373397.Google Scholar
Epstein, D. and O’Halloran, S. (1999) Delegating Powers: A Transaction Cost Politics Approach to Policymaking Under Separate Powers. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Ferejohn, J. and Shipan, C. (1990) Congressional Influence on Bureaucracy. Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization 6: 120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fernandez, S. (2005) Developing and Testing an Integrative Framework of Public Sector Leadership: Evidence from the Public Education Arena. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 15(2): 197217.Google Scholar
Finer, H. (1941) Administrative Responsibility in Democratic Government. Public Administration Review 1: 335350.Google Scholar
Frey, B. S. and Oberholzer-Gee, F. (1997) The Cost of Price Incentives: An Empirical Analysis of Motivation Crowding-Out. The American Economic Review 87(4): 746755.Google Scholar
Friedrich, C. J. (1940) Public Policy and the Nature of Administrative Responsibility. In Friedrich C. J. and Mason E. S. (eds.), Public Policy. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 324.Google Scholar
Gagné, M. and Deci, E. L. (2005) Self-Determination Theory and Work Motivation. Journal of Organizational Behavior 26(4): 331362.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gailmard, S. (2009) Multiple Principals and Oversight of Bureaucratic Policy-Making. Journal of Theoretical Politics 21: 161186.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gailmard, S. and Patty, J. W. (2007) Slackers and Zealots: Civil Service, Policy Discretion, and Bureaucratic Expertise. American Journal of Political Science 51(4): 873889.Google Scholar
Gailmard, S. and Patty, J. W. (2012) Learning While Governing: Expertise and Accountability in the Executive Branch. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Gilmour, R. S. and Halley, A. A. (eds.), (1994) Who Makes Public Policy?: The Struggle for Control Between Congress and the Executive. Chatham, NJ: Chatham House Publishers.Google Scholar
Grimmer J. and Stewart, B. M. (2013) Text as Data: The Promise and Pitfalls of Automatic Content Analysis Methods for Political Texts. Political Analysis 21(3): 267297.Google Scholar
Hackman, J. R. and Oldham, G. R. (1976) Motivation Through the Design of Work: Test of a Theory. Organizational Behavior and Human Performance 16(2): 250279.Google Scholar
Hopkins, D. J. and King, G. (2010) A Method of Automated Nonparametric Content Analysis for Social Science. American Journal of Political Science 54(1): 229247.Google Scholar
Houston, D. J. (2009) Motivating Knights or Knaves? Moving Beyond Performance-Related Pay for the Public Sector. Public Administration Review 69(1): 4357.Google Scholar
Huber, J. D. and Shipan, C. R. (2002) Deliberate Discretion? The Institutional Foundations of Bureaucratic Autonomy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Judge, T. A., Thoresen, C. J., Bono, J. E. and Patton, G. K. (2001) The Job Satisfaction–Job Performance Relationship: A Qualitative and Quantitative Review. Psychological Bulletin 127(3): 376407.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Kiewiet, R. and McCubbins, M. (1991) The Logic of Delegation: Congressional Parties and the Appropriation Process. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Kriner, D. and Schickler, E. (2013) The Policy Consequences of Congressional Investigations. Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association, Chicago, IL, April.Google Scholar
Kriner, D. and Schwartz, L. (2008) Divided Government and Congressional Investigations. Legislative Studies Quarterly 33: 295322.Google Scholar
Lee, J., Rainey, H. G. and Chun, Y. (2009) Of Politics and Purpose: Political Salience and Goal Ambiguity of U.S. Federal Agencies. Public Administration 87: 457484.Google Scholar
Lee, S.-Y. and Whitford, A. B. (2013) Assessing the Effects of Organizational Resources on Public Agency Performance: Evidence from the US Federal Government. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 23(3): 687712.Google Scholar
Light, P. C. (1993) Monitoring Government: Inspectors General and the Search for Accountability. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Light, P. C. (2006) The Tides of Reform Revisited: Patterns in Making Government Work, 1945–2002. Public Administration Review 66(1): 619.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
MacDonald, J. A. and McGrath, R. J. (forthcoming) Retrospective Congressional Oversight and the Dynamics of Legislative Influence over the Bureaucracy. Legislative Studies Quarterly (in press).Google Scholar
Markon, J., Nakashima, E. and Crites, A. (2014) Top-Level Turnover Makes it Harder for DHS to Stay on Top of Evolving Threats, http://www.washingtonpost.com/politics/top-level-turnover-makes-it-harder-for-dhs-to-stay-on-top-of-evolving-threats/2014/09/21/ca7919a6-39d7-11e4-9c9f-ebb47272e40e_story.html (accessed 8 January 2015).Google Scholar
Martin, A. D. and Quinn, K. M. (2002) Dynamic Ideal Point Estimation Via Markov Chain Monte Carlo for the U.S. Supreme Court, 1953–1999. Political Analysis 10(2): 134153.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mathieu, J. E. and Zajac, D. M. (1990) A Review and Meta-Analysis of the Antecedents, Correlates, and Consequences of Organizational Commitment. Psychological Bulletin 108(2): 171194.Google Scholar
May, P. J., Jochim, A. E. and Sapotichne, J. (2011) Constructing Homeland Security: An Anemic Policy Regime. Policy Studies Journal 39(2): 285307.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
May, P. J., Sapotichne, J. and Workman, S. (2009) Widespread Policy Disruption: Terrorism, Public Risks, and Homeland Security. Policy Studies Journal 37(2): 171194.Google Scholar
May, P. J., Workman, S. and Jones, B. D. (2008) Organizing Attention: Responses of the Bureaucracy to Agenda Disruption. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 18(4): 517541.Google Scholar
Mayhew, D. R. (2005) Divided We Govern: Party Control, Lawmaking, and Investigations, 1946–1990, 2nd ed. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
McCubbins, M. D. and Schwartz, T. (1984) Congressional Oversight Overlooked: Police Patrols Versus Fire Alarms. American Journal of Political Science 28(1): 165179.Google Scholar
McGrath, R. J. (2013) Congressional Oversight Hearings and Policy Control. Legislative Studies Quarterly 38(3): 353380.Google Scholar
Meier, K. J. (1975) Representative Bureaucracy: An Empirical Analysis. American Political Science Review 69: 526542.Google Scholar
Meier, K. J. (1997) Bureaucracy and Democracy: The Case for More Bureaucracy and Less Democracy. Public Administration Review 57(3): 193199.Google Scholar
Meier, K. J. and Nigro, L. G. (1976) Representative Bureaucracy and Policy Preferences. Public Administration Review 36(4): 458469.Google Scholar
Meyer, J. P., Stanley, D. J., Herscovitch, L. and Topolnytsky, L. (2002) Affective, Continuance, and Normative Commitment to the Organization: A Meta-Analysis of Antecedents, Correlates, and Consequences. Journal of Vocational Behavior 61(1): 2052.Google Scholar
Miller, G. J. (2005) The Political Evolution of Principal-Agent Models. Annual Review of Political Science 8: 203225.Google Scholar
Moe, T. M. (1989) The Politics of Bureaucratic Structure. In Chubb J. and Peterson P. (eds.), Can the Government Govern?. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution, 267329.Google Scholar
Ogul, M. S. and Rockman, B. A. (1990) Overseeing Oversight: New Departures and Old Problems. Legislative Studies Quarterly 15: 524.Google Scholar
Oleszek, W. J. (2001) Congressional Procedures and the Policy Process., 5th ed. Washington, DC: CQ Press.Google Scholar
O’Toole, L. J. and Meier, K. J. (1999) Modeling the Impact of Public Management: Implications of Structural Context. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 9(4): 505526.Google Scholar
Parker, D. C. W. and Dull, M. (2009) Divided We Quarrel: The Politics of Congressional Investigations. Legislative Studies Quarterly 34: 319345.Google Scholar
Parnell, A. (1980) Congressional Interference in Agency Enforcement: The IRS Experience. Yale Law Journal 89(7): 13601394.Google Scholar
Perry, J. L. and Wise, L. R. (1990) The Motivational Bases of Public Service. Public Administration Review 50(3): 367373.Google Scholar
Pham, H. H., Ginsburg, P. B. and Verdier, J. M. (2009) Medicare Governance and Provider Payment Policy. Health Affairs 28(5): 13821394.Google Scholar
Rainey, H. G. and Steinbauer, P. (1999) Galloping Elephants: Developing Elements of a Theory of Effective Government Organizations. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 9(1): 132.Google Scholar
Riketta, M. (2002) Attitudinal Organizational Commitment and Job Performance: A Meta-Analysis. Journal of Organizational Behavior 23(3): 257266.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rosenbloom, D. H. (1993) Editorial: Have an Administrative Rx? Don’t Forget the Politics!. Public Administration Review 53(6): 503507.Google Scholar
Ryan, R. M. and Deci, E. L. (2000) Self-Determination Theory and the Facilitation of Intrinsic Motivation, Social Development, and Well-Being. American psychologist 55(1): 6878.Google Scholar
Shapiro, S. A. (1994) Political Oversight and the Deterioration of Regulatory Policy. Administrative Law Review 46(1): 140.Google Scholar
Shipan, C. R. (2004) Regulatory Regimes, Agency Actions, and the Conditional Nature of Congressional Influence. American Political Science Review 98(3): 467480.Google Scholar
Smith, K. (2003) The Growth of Congressional Oversight. Paper presented at the 2003 meeting of the American Political Science Association, 27 August 2003, Philadelphia, PA.Google Scholar
Spector, P. E. (1986) Perceived Control by Employees: A Meta-Analysis of Studies Concerning Autonomy and Participation at Work. Human Relations 39(11): 10051016.Google Scholar
Tepper, B. J. (2000) Consequences of Abusive Supervision. Academy of Management Journal 43(2): 178190.Google Scholar
Tepper, B. J. (2007) Abusive Supervision in Work Organizations: Review, Synthesis, and Research Agenda. Journal of Management 33(3): 261289.Google Scholar
Tett, R. P. and Meyer, J. P. (1993) Job Satisfaction, Organizational Commitment, Turnover Intention, and Turnover: Path Analyses Based on Meta-Analytic Findings. Personnel Psychology 46(2): 259293.Google Scholar
Volden, C. (2002) Delegating Power to Bureaucracies: Evidence from the States. Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization 18(1): 187220.Google Scholar
Waldo, D. (1948) The Administrative State. Teaneck, NJ: Holmes & Meier Publishers.Google Scholar
Ward, K. D. (2014) Cultivating Public Service Motivation Through AmeriCorps Service: A Longitudinal Study. Public Administration Review 74(1): 114125.Google Scholar
Weingast, B. R. and Moran, M. J. (1983) Bureaucratic Discretion or Congressional Control? Regulatory Policymaking by the Federal Trade Commission. The Journal of Political Economy 91(5): 765800.Google Scholar
Whitford, A. B. (2005) The Pursuit of Political Control by Multiple Principals. Journal of Politics 67(1): 2849.Google Scholar
Wilson, J. Q. (1989) Bureaucracy: What Government Agencies Do and Why They Do It. New York, NY: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Wilson, W. (1887) The Study of Administration. In Shafritz J. M. and Hyde A. C. (eds.), Classics of Public Administration, 6th ed. Boston, MA: Thomson Wadsworth, 1628.Google Scholar
Wolf, P. J. (1993) A Case Survey of Bureaucratic Effectiveness in US Cabinet Agencies: Preliminary Results. Journal of Public Administration Research and Theory 3(2): 161181.Google Scholar
Wood, B. D. and Bohte, J. (2004) Political Transaction Costs and the Politics of Administrative Design. Journal of Politics 66: 176202.Google Scholar
Wooldridge, J. M. (2010) Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1 Oversight hearing days (1999–2011)Note: Figure created by summing all oversight hearing days for all agencies in a given year. Hearings can involve more than one agency at a time, so this can result in double-counting hearings. We show this double-counted measure of hearings activity as it more accurately captures total agency attention to congressional priorities.

Figure 1

Figure 2 Oversight hearings over time by department

Figure 2

Figure 3 Distribution of oversight hearings by departmentNote: Horizontal lines give the median for each agency, boxes give the bounds of the interquartile range and dots show outliers.

Figure 3

Figure 4 Agency autonomy by department

Figure 4

Figure 5 Job satisfaction by department

Figure 5

Table 1 Ordinary least squares models of agency autonomy and job satisfaction (1999–2011)

Supplementary material: PDF

Marvel and McGrath supplementary material

Appendix

Download Marvel and McGrath supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 400.9 KB