Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-cfpbc Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-19T01:44:55.224Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Old age support in kind

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  21 July 2009

KAZUTOSHI MIYAZAWA
Affiliation:
Faculty of Economics, Doshisha University, Kamigyo, Kyoto 6028580, Japan (e-mail: kazu@mail.doshisha.ac.jp)

Abstract

It has been argued whether a transfer policy for elderly people should be in kind or in cash. This paper presents a rationale to answer the question in an endogenous growth model with a two-way intrafamily transfer in middle age, education for the child as an inter-vivos transfer, and informal parental care in exchange for a bequest. We have two analytical results. First, a transfer in cash, such as a public pension, prevents economic growth because a strategic behavior concerning caregiving generates a disincentive effect on education. Second, a transfer in kind, such as public formal care, promotes economic growth because the valuation of the service generates an additional benefit of education, which dominates the disincentive effect. Our results show that old age support should be in kind rather than in cash in the context of economic growth and also welfare if bequests are strategic.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2009

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Altig, David and Davis, Steven J. (1989) Government debt, redistributive fiscal policies, and the interaction between borrowing constraints and intergenerational altruism. Journal of Monetary Economics, 24: 329.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Altig, David and Davis, Steven J. (1992) The timing of intergenerational transfers, tax policy, and aggregate savings. American Economic Review, 82: 11991220.Google Scholar
Altig, David and Davis, Steven J. (1993) Borrowing constraints and two-sided altruism with an application to social security. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 17: 467494.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Altonji, Joseph G., Hayashi, Fumio, and Kotlikoff, Laurence J. (1992) Is the extended family altruistically linked? Direct tests using micro data. American Economic Review, 82: 11771198.Google Scholar
Altonji, Joseph G., Hayashi, Fumio, and Kotlikoff, Laurence J. (1996) The effects of income and wealth on time and money transfers between parents and children. NBER Working Paper No. 5522.Google Scholar
Altonji, Joseph G., Hayashi, Fumio, and Kotlikoff, Laurence J. (1997) Parental altruism and inter vivos transfers: theory and evidence. Journal of Political Economy, 105: 11211166.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, Gary S. (1974) A theory of social interactions. Journal of Political Economy, 82: 10631093.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, Gary S. (1976) Altruism, egoism, and genetic fitness: economics and socio-biology. Journal of Economic Literature, 14: 817826.Google Scholar
Becker, Gary S. and Murphy, Kevin (1988) The family and the state. Journal of Law and Economics, 31: 118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bergstrom, Theodore C. (1989) A fresh look at the Rotten Kid theorem – and other household mysteries. Journal of Political Economy, 97: 11381159.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernheim, B. Douglas, Shleifer, Andei, and Summers, Lawrence H. (1985) The strategic bequest motive. Journal of Political Economy, 93: 10451076.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Besley, Timothy and Coate, Stephen (1991) Public provision of private goods and the redistribution of income. American Economic Review, 81: 979984.Google Scholar
Blackorby, Charles and Donaldson, David (1988) Cash versus kind, self-selection, and efficient transfers. American Economic Review, 78: 691700.Google Scholar
Blömquist, Sören and Christiansen, Vidar (1998) Price subsidies versus public provision. International Tax and Public Finance, 5: 283306.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bruce, Neil and Waldman, Michael (1990) The Rotten-Kid theorem meets the Samaritan's dilemma. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 105: 155165.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bruce, Neil and Waldman, Michael (1991) Transfer in kind: why they can be efficient and nonpaternalistic. American Economic Review, 81: 13451351.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M. (1968) What kind of redistribution do we want? Economica, 35: 185190.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caballé, Jordi (1995) Endogenous growth, human capital, and bequest in a life-cycle model. Oxford Economic Papers, 47: 156181.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coate, Stephen (1989) Cash versus direct food relief. Journal of Development Economics, 30: 199224.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coate, Stephen (1995) Altruism, the Samaritan's dilemma, and the government transfer policy. American Economic Review, 85: 4657.Google Scholar
Coate, Stephen, Johnson, Stephen, and Zeckhauser, Richard (1994) Pecuniary redistribution through in-kind programs. Journal of Public Economics, 55: 1940.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, Donald (1987) Motives for private income transfers. Journal of Political Economy, 95: 508546.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, Donald (1990) Intergenerational transfers and liquidity constraints. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 105: 187217.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, Donald, Hansen, Bruce E., and Jimenez, Emmanuel (2004) How responsive are private transfers to income? Evidence from a laissez-faire economy. Journal of Public Economics, 88: 21932219.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, Donald and Jakubson, George (1995) The connection between public transfers and private interfamily transfers. Journal of Public Economics, 57: 129167.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cox, Donald and Rank, Mark R. (1992) Inter-vivos transfers and intergenerational exchange. Review of Economics and Statistics, 74: 305314.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cremer, Helmuth and Gahvari, Firouz (1997) In-kind transfers, self-selection and optimal tax policy. European Economic Review, 41: 97114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diamond, Peter (2004) Social security. American Economic Review, 94: 124.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Drazen, Allan (1978) Government debt, human capital, and bequests in a life-cycle model. Journal of Political Economy, 86: 505516.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Engers, Maxim and Stern, Steven (2002) Long-term care and family bargaining. International Economic Review, 43: 73114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garfinkel, Irwin (1973) Is in-kind redistribution efficient? Quarterly Journal of Economics, 87: 320330.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guesnerie, Roger and Roberts, Kevin (1984) Effective policy tools and quantity controls. Econometrica, 52: 5986.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoerger, Thomas J., Picone, Gabriel A., and Sloan, Frank A. (1996) Public subsidies, private provision of care and living arrangements of the elderly. Review of Economics and Statistics, 78: 428440.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ireland, Norman J. (1990) The mix of social and private provision of goods and services. Journal of Public Economics, 43: 201219.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leonesio, Michael V. (1988) In-kind transfers and work incentives. Journal of Labor Economics, 6: 515529.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lindbeck, Assar, and Weibull, Jörgen W. (1988) Altruism and time consistency: the economics of fait accompli. Journal of Political Economy, 96: 11651182.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lucas, Robert E. Jr. (1988) On the mechanics of economic development. Journal of Monetary Economics, 22: 342.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McGarry, Kathleen (1999) Inter vivos transfers and intended bequests. Journal of Public Economics, 73: 321351.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miyazawa, Kazutoshi (2003) Public pensions and take-off. Journal of Pension Economics and Finance, 2: 2539.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miyazawa, Kazutoshi (2004) Simple criteria for growth-enhancing social security systems. FinanzArchiv, 60: 4262.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Munro, Alistair (1992) Self-selection and optimal in-kind transfers. Economic Journal, 102: 11841196.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nerlove, Marc, Razin, Assaf, and Sadka, Efraim (1988) A bequest-constrained economy: welfare analysis. Journal of Public Economics, 37: 203220.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nichols, Albert L. and Zeckhauser, Richard J. (1982) Targeting transfers through restrictions on recipients. American Economic Review, 72: 372377.Google Scholar
OECD (1996) Caring for frail elderly people: policies in evolution. Social Policy Studies 19, Paris.Google Scholar
Pezzin, Liliana E., Kemper, Peter, and Reschovsky, James (1994) Does publicly provided home care substitute for family care? Journal of Human Resources, 31: 650676.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pezzin, Liliana E. and Schone, Barbara Steinberg (1997) The allocation of resources in intergenerational households: adult children and their elderly parents. American Economic Review, 87: 460464.Google Scholar
Pezzin, Liliana E. and Schone, Barbara Steinberg (1999) Intergenerational household formation, female labor supply and informal caregiving. Journal of Human Resources, 34: 475503.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pollak, Robert A. (1988) Tied transfers and paternalistic preferences. American Economic Review, 78: 240244.Google Scholar
Rangazas, Peter C. (1996) Fiscal policy and endogenous growth in a bequest-constrained economy. Oxford Economic Papers, 48: 5274.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schoeni, Robert F. (1997) Private interhousehold transfers of money and time: new empirical evidence. Review of Income and Wealth, 43: 423448.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schoeni, Robert F. (2002) Does unemployment insurance displace familial assistance? Public Choice, 110: 99119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thurow, Lester C. (1974) Cash versus in-kind transfers. American Economic Review, 64: 190195.Google Scholar
Tomes, Nigel (1981) The family, inheritance, and the intergenerational transmissions of inequality. Journal of Political Economy, 89: 928958.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilhelm, Mark O. (1996) Bequest behavior and the effect of heirs' earnings: testing the altruistic model of bequests. American Economic Review, 86: 874892.Google Scholar