Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-jr42d Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-16T10:07:36.442Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Intellectual property protection and antitrust in the developing world: crisis, coercion, and choice

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 May 2009

Susan K. Sell
Affiliation:
Assistant Professor of Political Science at the George Washington University, Washington, D.C.
Get access

Abstract

After the economic crisis of the early 1980s, developing countries adopted new policies regarding intellectual property protection only as a result of a coercive U.S. strategy, consistent with a neorealist explanation based on power. Targeted countries have complied only on paper, not in practice, however. In contrast, hegemonic powers have not employed overt coercion in the area of antitrust policy, consistent with interpretivist neoliberalism, which emphasizes learning and voluntarism. A nuanced analysis of power and ideas is necessary to account for the differences between the cases. The different mechanisms through which the new policies have been adopted suggest different prospects for these new policies.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The IO Foundation 1995

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1. Ikenberry, G. John and Kupchan, Charles, “Socialization and Hegemonic Power,” International Organization 44 (Summer 1990), pp. 283315CrossRefGoogle Scholar. The quotation is drawn from p. 285 fn. 3.

2. This phrase is adapted from comments by Alcorn, Marshall at a seminar entitled “The Rhetoric of Disciplined Inquiry,” George Washington University, Washington, D.C., 9 10 1993Google Scholar.

3. See Gray, Clive, “Antitrust as a Component of Policy Reform: What Role for Developing Countries?” in Perkins, Dwight and Roemer, Michael, eds., Reforming Economic Systems in Developing Countries (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard Institute for International Development, 1991), pp. 403–40Google Scholar; World Bank, Korea: Managing the Industrial Transition, vol. 1, The Conduct of Industrial Policy (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 1987), p. 74Google Scholar; and World Bank, Korea: Managing the Industrial Transition, vol. 2, Selected Topics and Case Studies (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 1987), pp. 34, 80, and 88Google Scholar.

4. United Nations General Assembly, “The Set of Multilateral Agreed Equitable Principles and Rules for the Control of Restrictive Business Practices,” TD/RBP/CONF/10/Rev. 1 (New York: United Nations, 1981)Google Scholar.

5. As Martin, Lisa argues in Coercive Cooperation (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1992)Google Scholar, such incentives may be supplied by either hegemonic power or institutions. However, in the intellectual property case, international institutions played a minimal role in providing incentives for developing countries to change their policies of lax protection.

6. Particularly in South Korea and Taiwan, antitrust policies have become a potent political weapon in the hands of democratic reformers. See Sell, Susan K., “Antitrust in Korea and Taiwan: The Link Between Politics and Money in the Context of Democratization,” prepared for annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, New York, 1–4 09 1994Google Scholar. In the text that follows, the terms “Korea” and “Korean” refer to South Korea.

7. Agosin, Manuel and Gold, David, “Recent Trends in FDI and Related Activities by TNCs,” The CTC Reporter, no. 21, Spring 1986, p. 21Google Scholar.

8. Industry associations in service, investment, high-technology, agricultural chemical, pharmaceutical, and entertainment sectors lobbied Congress for more effective intellectual property protection abroad. Among the most active groups were the Associations of: the Pharmaceutical Manufacturers; the Chemical Manufacturers; the Semiconductor Industry; and the International Intellectual Property Alliance (an umbrella organization of eight trade associations: American Publishers, Inc.; American Film Marketing; Data Processing and Service Organizations; Computer Software and Services Industry; Business Software Alliance; Computer and Business Equipment Manufacturers; National Music Publishers; the Recording Industry of America; and Motion Picture Association of America).

9. See p. 282 of Sykes, Alan O., “Constructive Unilateral Threats in International Commercial Relations: The Limited Case for Section 301,” Law and Policy in International Business, vol. 23, no. 2, 1992, pp. 263330Google Scholar.

10. Sykes, , “Constructive Unilateral Threats in International Commercial Relations,” p. 313Google Scholar.

11. Mossinghoff, Gerald J., “For Better International Protection,” Les Nouvelles 26 (06 1991), pp. 7579 and p. 76 in particularGoogle Scholar.

12. Ryan, Michael P., “Strategy and Compliance with Bilateral Trade and Dispute Settlement Agreements: USTR's Section 301 Experience in the Pacific Basin,” Michigan Journal of International Law 12 (Summer 1991), pp. 799827 and p. 824 in particularGoogle Scholar.

13. Software Piracy: Self-Defense the Best Choice for Victims,” Business International, vol. 24, 20 07 1992, p. 250Google Scholar.

14. Greguras, Fred M. and Lee, Moon Sung, “Software Licensing in Korea,” Les Nouvelles 27 (12 1992), pp. 215–19 and p. 217 in particularGoogle Scholar.

15. “Differences Over Code on Patents,” Latin American Regional Reports—Brazil, RB-91–04, (London: Latin American Newsletters, 2 05 1991), p. 4Google Scholar.

16. Mossinghoff, , “For Better International Protection,” p. 77Google Scholar.

17. Pearson, John, “The Patent Pirates are Finally Walking the Plank,” Business Week, Industrial/Technology ed., 17 02 1992, p. 127Google Scholar.

18. Neuman, William, “IPR Protection Improves, but Reforms not Uniform,” Business Latin America, 20 04 1992, p. 127Google Scholar.

19. Studebaker, Scott, “Brazil: Constitutional Revision Session Floundering,” Latin American Law and Business Report 2 (04 1994), pp. 1113 and p. 12 in particularGoogle Scholar.

20. Notes, Market, Latin American Law and Business Report 1 (08 1993), p. 32Google Scholar.

21. Simon, Helen J., “Unfair Practices in the Spotlight,” Business Latin America, 25 01 1993, pp. 67Google Scholar.

22. Mossinghoff, , “For Better International Protection,” p. 76Google Scholar.

23. Shore, Chris, “The Thai Copyright Case and Possible Limitations of Extraterritorial Jurisdiction in Actions Taken Under Section 301 of the Trade Act of 1974,” Law and Policy in International Business, vol. 23, no. 3, 1992, pp. 725–18 and p. 729 in particularGoogle Scholar.

24. “Thai-U.S. Trade Relations Skate on Thin Ice over IP Rights Inaction,” Business Asia, 13 November 1989, pp. 371–72.

25. Ibid., p. 372.

26. Shore, , “The Thai Copyright Case and Possible Limitations of Extraterritorial Jurisdiction in Actions Taken Under Section 301 of the Trade Act of 1974,” p. 747 n. 108Google Scholar.

27. McDonald, Hamish, “The Late Convert: India Wins Reprieve in Patent Row with U.S.,” Far Eastern Economic Review, 5 12 1991, pp. 6465Google Scholar. The quotation is from p. 65.

28. Export values are from U.S. Bureau of the Census, Statistical Abstract of the United States: 1993, 113th ed. (Washington, D.C.: Bureau of the Census 1993), p. 813, table 1351Google Scholar.

29. Simone, Joseph T. Jr, “Improving Protection of Intellectual Property,” China Business Review 19 (03/04 1992), p. 9Google Scholar.

30. Shenon, Philip, “Chinese Accused of Pirating Disks,” New York Times, 18 08 1994, p. DlGoogle Scholar.

31. Ibid.

32. Ibid., p. D17.

33. Notes, Market, Latin American Law and Business Report, vol. 2, no. 1, 01 1994, p. 31Google Scholar.

34. Figures for both the Mexican and Thai cases are from Mossinghoff, , “For Better International Protection,” p. 76Google Scholar.

35. Traditionally, developing countries have favored the use of exclusive compulsory licenses in cases in which the patentee fails to exploit commercially the patent in the developing country. Under exclusive compulsory licenses, the patent rights are transferred to local parties. As Pfanner points out, “when an exclusive license is granted, the patent owner is excluded from using his own invention.” See Pfanner, Klaus, “Compulsory Licensing of Patents: Survey and Current Trends,” Sartryckur NIR Nordiskt Immateriellt Rattsskydd, doc. 1 NIR 1/85, p. 5Google Scholar.

36. This point was suggested by an anonymous reviewer for International Organization.

37. Summarized from Becerril, Oscar, “Mexico's New Law Liberalizes Technology Transfer,” Les Nouvelles 27 (03 1992), pp. 45Google Scholar.

38. Mike Privatera is quoted in Neuman, William, “IPR Protection Improves, But Reforms Not Uniform,” Business Latin America, 20 04 1992, p. 127Google Scholar.

39. Biersteker, Thomas, “The ‘Triumph’ of Liberal Economic Ideas in the Developing World,” in Stallings, Barbara, ed., The New International Context of Development (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, forthcoming), manuscript p. 13Google Scholar.

40. In the early 1980s, the East Asian “miracles” were inaccurately held up as paragons of free market economics. Much of the subsequent East Asian scholarship has exposed this fallacy and demonstrated the importance of extensive state intervention in these countries' development policies. On the demonstration effect, see Ikenberry, G. John, “The International Spread of Privatization Policies: Inducements, Learning, and ‘Policy Bandwagoning,’” in Suleiman, Ezra and Waterbury, John, The Political Economy of Public Sector Reform and Privatization (Boulder, Colo.: Westview, 1990), pp. 88110Google Scholar.

41. In fiscal year 1988, the following twenty-six countries accounted for 85 percent of World Bank lending geared to reforming industrial and trade policies: Argentina, Brazil, Chile, China, Colombia, Ecuador, Egypt, Greece, Hong Kong, Hungary, India, Indonesia, Malaysia, Mexico, Morocco, Nigeria, Pakistan, Peru, Philippines, Poland, Republic of Korea, Singapore, Thailand, Turkey, Venezuela, and Yugoslavia. See Frischtak, Claudio R., Competition Policies for Industrializing Countries, Policy and Research Series no. 7 (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 1981), p. 25 nn. 3 and 4Google Scholar.

42. Vinod Aggarwal suggested this point in his comments on an earlier draft of the present article.

43. UNCTAD, Report of the Second United Nations Conference to Review All Aspects of the Multilaterally Agreed Equitable Principles and Rules for the Control of Restrictive Business Practices, TD/RBP/CONF.3/9 (Geneva: UNCTAD, 11 02 1991), p. 1, par. 3Google Scholar.

44. Ibid., p. 2, par. 7.

45. Ibid., p. 15, par. 46.

46. Wagner, Stanley P., “Antitrust: The Korean Experience 1981–85,” The Antitrust Bulletin, Summer 1987, pp. 471522Google Scholar. The quotation is from p. 500.

47. Boner, Roger Alan and Krueger, Reinald, The Basics of Antitrust Policy, Technical Paper no. 160 (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 1991), p. 43 n. 92Google Scholar.

48. Wagner, , “Antitrust,” p. 505Google Scholar.

49. Ibid., p. 516.

50. UNCTAD, “Draft Report of the Intergovernmental Working Group of Experts on Restrictive Business Practices on its Eleventh Session,” TD/B/RBP/L.58/Add. 1, UNCTAD, Geneva, 26 11 1992, p. 9, par. 40Google Scholar.

51. “Hyundai Founder Sentenced for Violating Election Laws,” New York Times, 2 November 1993, p. A10.

52. Koo is quoted in Cheeseman, Bruce, “Hyundai Probe Turns Up Heat on Big Business,” South China Morning Post, 13 12 1992, p. 2Google Scholar.

53. Burton, John, “South Korea to Probe Chaebol Power,” Financial Times, 7 04 1993, p. 7Google Scholar.

54. Ibid.

55. UNCTAD, Report of the Second United Nations Conference to Review All Aspects of the Multilaterally Agreed Equitable Principles and Rules for the Control of Restrictive Business Practices,” p. 16, par. 49Google Scholar.

56. Management Alert, Business Latin America, 3 08 1992, p. 268Google Scholar.

57. Hughes, Thomas, “Venezuela: Recent Developments,” Latin American Law and Business Report 2 (02 1994), p. 23Google Scholar.

58. Hughes, Thomas, “Venezuela: Recent Developments,” Latin American Law and Business Report 1 (08 1993), pp. 2728Google Scholar.

59. Hughes, Thomas, “Venezuela: Recent Developments,” Latin American Law and Business Report 1 (09 1993), pp. 3233Google Scholar.

60. Hughes, Thomas, “Venezuela: Recent Developments,” Latin American Law and Business Report 1 (11 1993), p. 26Google Scholar.

61. The Chilean government had adopted neoclassical economic reforms in the early 1970s after the takeover by Augusto Pinochet. For a discussion of this earlier period see Foxley, Alejandro, Latin American Experiments in Neoconservative Economics (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1983)Google Scholar.

62. UNCTAD, Report of the Second United Nations Conference to Review All Aspects of the Multilateralfy Agreed Equitable Principles and Rules for the Control of Restrictive Business Practices, p. 26, par. 91Google Scholar.

63. Ibid.

64. This paragraph is based on Neto-Advogados, Pinheiro, “Investigation of Pharmaceutical Industry for Abuse of Economic Power,” Latin American Law and Business Report 1 (04 1993), pp. 2324Google Scholar.

65. This paragraph is based on Studebaker, Scott, “Brazil: Economic Plan, Privatization, Status of Constitutional Congress, and Other Recent Developments,” Latin American Law and Business Report 2 (02 1994), p. 8Google Scholar.

66. Delgado, Natalia and Martin, Steven, “Mexico: The New Law of Economic Competition,” Latin American Law and Business Report 1 (06 1993), p. 27Google Scholar.

67. Lang, Jeffrey and Brank, Laura, “A Step in the Right Direction: Unlocking the Mexican Energy Market,” Latin American Law and Business Report 1 (08 1993), p. 14Google Scholar.

68. Notes, Market, “Mexico's SECOFI Implements Competition Law,” Latin American Law and Business Report 1 (05 1993), pp. 3435Google Scholar.

69. Tata Timken Shows India's Monopolies Law is Losing Its Teeth,” Business Asia 4 (09 1989), p. 292Google Scholar.

70. Ibid.

71. Ibid., p. 293.

73. Dubey, Suman, “India Clears Some Foreign Investments, Sending Bullish Signal on Reform Drive,” Wall Street Journal, 24 06 1993, p. A6Google Scholar.

73. “Indian Economy, Pepsi Generation,” The Economist, 6 June 1990, p. 40.

74. Sarkar, Jayanta, “Back in Charge: India's Reforms Entice Foreign Firms to Raise Their Profile,” Far Eastern Economic Review, 8 07 1993, pp. 4950Google Scholar.

75. Ibid.

76. I thank an anonymous reviewer for International Organization for suggesting this example to me.

77. UNCTAD, Report of the Second United Nations Conference to Review All Aspects of the Multilaterally Agreed Equitable Principles and Rules for the Control of Restrictive Business Practices,” p. 17, par. 56–57Google Scholar.

78. Based on Bowen, Sally, “Peru Opens Up Economy with Deluge of Laws,” Financial Times 20 11 1991, p. 8Google Scholar, quoted in Guislain, Pierre, Divestiture of State Enterprises: An Overview of the Legal Framework, technical paper no. 186 (Washington, D.C.: World Bank, 1992), p. 10 n. 27Google Scholar.

79. UNCTAD, Report of the Second United Nations Conference to Review All Aspects of the Multilaterally Agreed Equitable Principles and Rules for the Control of Restrictive Business Practices, p. 18, par. 58Google Scholar.

80. Ibid., p. 38, par. 144.

81. UNCTAD, “Draft Report of the Intergovernmental Working Group of Experts on Restrictive Business Practices on Its Eleventh Session,” p. 10, par. 43Google Scholar.

82. UNCTAD, Review of the Operation of and Experience Arising from the Application and Implementation of the Set of Multilateral Agreed Equitable Principles and Rules for the Control of Restrictive Business Practices, TD/B/RBP/89/Add.l (Geneva: UNCTAD, 30 09 1992), p. 2, par. 4–9Google Scholar.

83. UNCTAD, Report of the Second United Nations Conference to Review All Aspects of the Multilaterally Agreed Equitable Principles and Rules for the Control of Restrictive Business Practices, p. 29, par. 104Google Scholar.

84. UNCTAD, “Adoption of the Agenda and Organization of Work,” TD/B/RBP/86, UNCTAD, Geneva, 21 07 1992Google Scholar.

85. Ibid., p. 2.

86. UNCTAD, Report of the Second United Nations Conference to Review All Aspects of the Multilaterally Agreed Equitable Principles and Rules for the Control of Restrictive Business Practices, pp. 2021, par. 70 and 71Google Scholar.

87. Ikenberry, and Kupchan, , “Socialization and Hegemonic Power,” p. 290Google Scholar.

88. Ibid., p. 291.

89. Sherwood, Robert M., “New Theory of Conductivity in Licensing,” Les Nouvelles (12 1989), p. 187Google Scholar.

90. Ibid.

91. Merges, Robert, “Battle of the Lateralisms: Intellectual Property and Trade,” Boston University International Law Journal 8 (Fall 1990), pp. 239–46Google Scholar. The quotation is from p. 246.

92. On the Paris Convention, see Mallott, Robert, “1990s Issue: Intellectual Property Rights,” Les Nouvelles (12 1989), p. 152Google Scholar. I thank an anonymous reviewer for International Organization for providing me with the INFAST example.

93. Liu, Paul, “A Review of Intellectual Property Laws in Taiwan: Proposals to Curb Piracy and Counterfeiting in a Developing Country,” Brigham Young University Law Review vol. 5, no. 3, 1988, pp. 619–42 and p. 630 in particularGoogle Scholar.

94. Ibid., p. 630.

95. Ibid.

96. In the recently concluded Uruguay Round the provisions of the Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS) include important exemptions for developing countries. As Kent points out, developing countries “obtained a major concession, which would allow them to continue to pursue conscious policies of drug patent exemption.” See Kent, Christopher, “NAFTA, TRIPS Affect IP,” Les Nouvelles 28 (12 1993), p. 176Google Scholar.

97. Fleischer, Lowell, “Round of Presidential Elections will Determine Whether Region will Continue Economic and Political Reform,” Latin American Law and Business Report 2 (01 1994), p. 2Google Scholar.