Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-c4f8m Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-19T04:52:28.479Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Explaining the non-proliferation regime: anomalies for contemporary international relations theory

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 May 2009

Roger K. Smith
Affiliation:
candidate in the Department of Government at Georgetown University.
Get access

Abstract

This article reconciles common policy usage with scholarly definition. The system of cooperation on non-proliferation has often been termed an international “regime,” but there has not been any systematic effort to determine if this is actually true. The discussion also attempts to reconcile the formation and maintenance of this system of cooperation with contemporary international relations theory. The central argument is that the system of international cooperation on non-proliferation does constitute a regime, but that such a regime presents a serious anomaly for contemporary theory. The article concludes that power and egoistic self-interest are inadequate to account for the regime's formation and maintenance. The inadequacies of both the hegemonic stability and functional theories point towards another independent variable that needs central consideration in regime analysis: knowledge and learning.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The IO Foundation 1987

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1. Krasner, Stephen D., “Structural Causes and Regime Consequences: Regimes as Intervening Variables,” in Krasner, , ed., International Regimes (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1983), p. ”1Google Scholar. The book contains all the articles originally published in the journal International Organization 36 (Spring 1982)Google Scholar. Subsequent citations will be to the book rather than the special issue of the journal. For a recent critique of regime analysis, see Kratochwil, Friedrich and Ruggie, John Gerard, “International Organization: A State of the Art on an Art of the State,” International Organization 40 (Autumn 1986), pp. 753–75CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

2. Robert Jervis, “Security Regimes,” in Krasner, ibid., pp. 173–195. See also two other related works by Jervis, : “Cooperation Under the Security Dilemma,” World Politics 31 (01 1978), pp. 167186CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and From Balance to Concert: A Study of International Security Cooperation,” World Politics 38 (10 1985), pp. 5878CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Also see Evera, Stephen Van, “Why Cooperation Failed in 1914,” World Politics 38 (10 1985), pp. 80117CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Downs, George W. et al. , “Arms Races and Cooperation,” World Politics 38 (10 1985), pp. 118146CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

3. Some of the recent literature on non-proliferation in which a “regime” is presumed to exist includes: Nye, Joseph S., “Maintaining the Non-Proliferation Regime,” International Organization 35 (Winter 1981), pp. 1538CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Potter, William C., Nuclear Power and Proliferation: An Interdisciplinary Approach (Cambridge, Mass.: Oelgescher, 1982)Google Scholar; Beckman, Robert L., Nuclear Non-Proliferation: Congress and the Control of Peaceful Nuclear Activities (Boulder: Westview, 1985)Google Scholar; Snyder, Jed C. and Wells, Samuel F., eds., Limiting Nuclear Proliferation (Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger, 1985)Google Scholar; and Jones, Rodney W. et al. , The Nuclear Suppliers and Non-Proliferation: International Policy Choices (Lexington, Mass.: Lexington, 1985)Google Scholar.

4. The definition of the theory of hegemonic stability used in this article draws largely from the work of Robert O. Keohane, who has given the theory its intellectual prominence through his criticisms and revisions. See Keohane, and Nye, Joseph S., Power and Interdependence: World Politics in Transition (Boston: Little Brown, 1977), pp. 3853Google Scholar; Keohane, , “The Theory of Hegemonic Stability and Changes in International Economic Regimes,” in Holsti, Ole R. et al. , eds., Change in the International System, (Boulder: Westview, 1980), pp. 131162Google Scholar; Keohane, , “The Demand for International Regimes,” in Krasner, , International Regimes, pp. 141172Google Scholar; and Keohane, , After Hegemony: Cooperation and Discord in the World Political Economy (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1984)Google Scholar. For a sophisiticated, historically-based theory of why hegemons decline, see Gilpin, Robert, War and Change in World Politics (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1982)Google Scholar. A recent article that critiques the theory of hegemonic stability in rigorous detail is Snidal, Duncan, “The Limits of Hegemonic Stability Theory,” International Organization 39 (Autumn 1985) pp. 579614CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

5. Axelrod, Robert and Keohane, Robert O., “Achieving Cooperation under Anarchy: Strategies and Institutions,” World Politics 38 (10 1985), pp. 252253CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

6. Keohane, , After Hegemony, pp. 85109Google Scholar; see also Keohane, “The Demand for International Regimes.” For two thoughtful reviews of the functional theory, see Young, Oran R., “International Regimes: Toward a New Theory of Institutions,” World Politics 39 (10 1986), p. 104122CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Rosenau, James N., “Before Cooperation: Hegemons, Regimes, and Habit-Driven Actors in World Politics,” International Organization 40 (Autumn 1986), pp. 849894CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

7. See note 3 for current literature that addresses these issues in depth. For recent reviews of the 1985 Nuclear Non-Proliferation Treaty Review Conference, see the following articles in Arms Control Today 15 (10 1985)Google Scholar: Lewis A. Dunn, “Standing up for the NPT”; Charles N. Van Doren, “Outlook Brightens for the NPT Regime”; and Leonard S. Spector, “Unfinished Business at the NPT Review.” See also Reiss, Mitchell, “Beyond the 1985 NPT Review Conference,” Survival 27 (09/10 1985)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Dunn, Lewis A., “Building on Success: the NPT at Fifteen,” Survival 28 (05/06, 1986)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

8. For a discussion of the ambiguity surrounding these key terms, see Haas, Ernst B., “The Balance of Power: Prescription, Concept, or Propaganda?World Politics 6 (07 1953)Google Scholar; Wolfers, Arnold, “National Security as an Ambiguous Symbol,” in Wolfers, , Discord and Collaboration: Essays on International Politics (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press1, 1962)Google Scholar; and Keohane, Robert O., “Reciprocity in International Relations,” International Organization 40 (Winter 1986)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

9. Ruggie, John Gerard, “International Responses to Technology: Concepts and Trends,” International Organization 34 (Summer, 1975), p. 570Google Scholar.

10. Krasner, , “Structural Causes,” p. 2Google Scholar.

11. Ibid., p. 3.

12. Jervis, “Security Regimes,” passim.

13. Krasner, , “Structural Causes,” p. 3Google Scholar; see also Ruggie, John Gerard, “International Regimes, Transactions, and Change: Embedded Liberalism in the Postwar Economic Order,” in Krasner, , International Regimes, pp. 195231Google Scholar.

14. Nye, , “Maintaining the Non-proliferation Regime” pp. 1516Google Scholar. The view that few nuclear weapon states is better than more is by no means universally shared. A prominent international relations scholar who argues the opposite is Kenneth N. Waltz; see “What Will the Spread of Nuclear Weapons Do to the World?” in King, John Kerry, ed., International Political Effects of the Spread of Nuclear Weapons (Washington: Government Printing Office, 1979)Google Scholar; and Waltz, , The Spread of Nuclear Weapons: More May Be Better, Adelphi Paper 171 (London: International Institute for Strategic Studies, 1981)Google Scholar. A scholar whose recent work argues for the “management” of proliferation instead of its prevention, especially in the Middle East, is Shai Feldman; see Israel's Nuclear Deterrence: A Strategy for the 1980s (New York: Columbia University Press, 1982)Google Scholar; and “Managing Nuclear Proliferation,” in Snyder, and Wells, , Limiting Nuclear Proliferation, pp. 301318Google Scholar. For a recent consideration of whether more or fewer nuclear weapon states would be desirable, see Berkowitz, Bruce D., “Proliferation, Deterrence and the Likelihood of War,” Journal of Conflict Resolution (03 1985), pp. 5782Google Scholar.

15. U.S. Arms Control and Disarmament Agency, Arms Control and Disarmament Agreements: Texts and Histories of Negotiations (Washington: ACDA, 1982), pp. 9195Google Scholar.

16. See Quester, George, “Nuclear Proliferation: Linkages and Solutions,” International Organization 33 (Autumn 1979)CrossRefGoogle Scholar, passim.

17. See Dunn, Lewis A., “Some Reflections on the ‘Dove's Dilemma,’” International Organization 35 (Winter 1981)CrossRefGoogle Scholar, passim.

18. Nye, , “Maintaining the Non-Proliferation Regime,” p. 17Google Scholar.

19. See Snyder, Jed C., “Iraq,” and Cronin, Richard P., “India and Pakistan,” in Snyder, and Wells, , Limiting Nuclear Proliferation, pp. 342, 59–88Google Scholar.

20. For the consequences of American legislation on U.S. relations with certain emerging nuclear states, and the impact of that legislation on those nascent nuclear programs, see Spector, Leonard S., Nuclear Proliferation Today (Cambridge, Mass: Ballinger, 1984)Google Scholar.

21. See Beckman, Nuclear Non-Proliferation, passim. For a prefiguration of the Carter administration's non-proliferation policy, see the Ford/Mitre report by the Nuclear Energy Study Group, Nuclear Power: Issues and Choices (Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger, 1977)Google Scholar.

22. Jervis, , “Security Regimes,” p. 178Google Scholar.

23. Most of these conditions are drawn from Jervis, ibid., passim; also see the sources cited in note 2.

24. Jervis, , “Security Regimes,” p. 178Google Scholar.

25. Ibid.

26. Strange, Susan, “Cave! Hic Dragones: A Critique of Regime Analysis,” in Krasner, , International Regimes, p. 345Google Scholar.

27. Krasner, , “Structural Causes,” p. 7Google Scholar; also in that same volume see the arguments of Stein, Arthur A., “Coordination and Collaboration: Regimes in an Anarchic World,” pp. 115140Google Scholar; and Keohane, , “The Demand for International Regimes,” pp. 141172Google Scholar.

28. For a discussion of the absolute versus relative size of hegemons and the contrast between coercive and benevolent leadership in the formation of regimes, see Snidal, , “The Limits of Hegemonic Stability Theory,” pp. 588590Google Scholar.

29. Keohane, and Nye, , Power and Interdependence, p. 44Google Scholar (emphasis added); see also Keohane, , After Hegemony, pp. 3239Google Scholar.

30. See Keohane, and Nye, , Power and Interdependence, pp. 3860Google Scholar.

31. Snidal, , “The Limits of Hegemonic Stability Theory,” p. 593Google Scholar.

32. Gilpin, War and Change, passim.

33. Clausen, Peter A., “US Nuclear Exports and the Non-Proliferation Regime,” in Snyder, and Wells, , Limiting Nuclear Proliferation, p. 190Google Scholar.

34. See Beckman, , Nuclear Non-Proliferation, pp. 2935Google Scholar.

35. For introductions to the “trade regime,” see Lipson, Charles, “The Transformation of Trade: The Sources and Effects of Regime Change,” in Krasner, , International Regimes, pp. 233272Google Scholar; and Jock A. Finlayson and Mark W. Zacher, “The GATT and the Regulation of Trade Barriers: Regime Dynamics and Functions,” in Krasner, ibid., pp. 273–314; also in the Krasner volume, see Ruggie, “International Regimes, Transactions, and Change: Embedded Liberalism in the Postwar Economic Order.”

36. In contrast to this line of reasoning David H. Blake and Robert S. Walters argue that the postwar multilateral agreements on trade and money were designed to “facilitate the perpetuation of American preeminence,” The Politics of Global Economic Relations (Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall, 1983), p. 2Google Scholar.

37. Safeguards were initially administered on a bilateral basis by the United States and then transferred to the International Atomic Energy Agency (IAEA) after the agency's inspection procedures were established in 1960.

38. This is not to say that the United States did not attempt to “dissuade” countries, such as France, from pursuing a nuclear weapons program. France, with its own domestic sources of uranium and privileged access to sources in former French colonies, was not completely at the mercy of the stranglehold on uranium supplies that the United States and Britain (through the Commonwealth) held, but it was vulnerable. In 1956 and 1965, France attempted to purchase Canadian uranium on an unrestricted basis. Both times the United States objected, and both times the sale fell through. Eventually, the Canadian government decided that all sales of uranium to any state, including the United States, would be subject to a peaceful-uses-only clause. In the “Honeywell incident” (also in 1965), the United States prevented the sale of computers to France that could aid the efforts to build a force de frappé. See Scheinman, Lawrence, Atomic Energy in France Under the Fourth Republic (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1965), pp. 176–84Google Scholar; and Scheinman, , “Security and a Transnational System: The Case of Nuclear Energy,” International Organization 25 (Summer 1971), pp. 637638CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

39. On the U.S.-U.S.S.R. context, see Henry Sokolski, “Atoms for Peace: A Non-Proliferation Primer?” Arms Control (September 1980), passim.

40. On the politics of the NPT negotiations, see Young, Elizabeth, A Farewell to Arms Control (Hammondsworth, U.K.: Penguin, 1972)Google Scholar; and Quester, George, The Politics of Nuclear Proliferation (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1973)Google Scholar. For an insightful treatment of the tensions between American alliance and non-proliferation policies, see Bader, William, The United States and the Spread of Nuclear Weapons (New York: Pegasus, 1968)Google Scholar.

41. On the “reactor wars” and U.S. penetration in the European market, see Bupp, Irvin C. and Derian, Jean-Claude, Light Water: How the Nuclear Dream Dissolved (New York: Basic, 1978)Google Scholar; and Nau, Henry, National Politics and International Technology: Nuclear Reactor Development in Western Europe (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1974)Google Scholar.

42. Jaskow, Paul, “The International Nuclear Industry Today,” Foreign Affairs 54 (Summer 1976), p. 792Google Scholar.

43. Haas, Ernst B., “Why Collaborate? Issue Linkage and International Regimes,” World Politics 33 (04 1980), p. 371Google Scholar.

44. Keohane, , After Hegemony, p. 45Google Scholar.

45. The question of whether the United States is still a hegemon is not yet a closed question. See Strange, Susan, “Still an Extraordinary Power: America's Role in a Global Monetary System,” in Lombra, Raymond E. and Witte, William E., eds., Political Economy of International and Domestic Monetary Relations (Ames: Iowa State University Press, 1982)Google Scholar; and Russett, Bruce, “The Mysterious Case of Vanishing Hegemony: Or Is Mark Twain Really Dead?International Organization 39 (Spring 1985)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

46. Clausen, , “US Nuclear Exports,” in Snyder and Wells, Limiting Nuclear Proliferation, p. 201Google Scholar.

47. There is, of course, considerable circumstantial evidence that South Africa (possibly in conjunction with Israel) exploded a nuclear device in 1979. For a review of this evidence, see Washington Office on Africa Educational Fund, “The September 27, 1979 Mystery Flash: Did South Africa Detonate a Nuclear Bomb?” (21 May 1985). What makes this report so interesting is that it relies heavily on U.S. Naval Research Laboratory documents. For a more general review of South Africa's status as a nuclear threshold state, see Jastrow, Robert, ‘South Africa,” in Snyder, and Wells, , Limiting Nuclear Proliferation, pp. 146180Google Scholar. The widely held belief that Jerusalem secretly possessed nuclear weapons was recently given additional credence; based on the testimony of Mordechai Vanunu, a former employee of the Dimona nuclear plant, London's Sunday Times reported on 5 October 1986 that Israel had stockpiled about 100 atomic weapons over the last twenty years, making Israel the sixth-ranked nuclear power in the world.

48. Nye, , “Maintaining the Non-Proliferation Regime,” p. 15Google Scholar.

49. Dunn, , “Building on Success,” pp. 230231Google Scholar.

50. On the Carter administration's emphasis on utilizing “supplier leverage,” see Beckman, Nuclear Non-Proliferation; Nye, Joseph S., “Non-Proliferation: A Long Term Strategy,” Foreign Affairs 56 (Spring 1978)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Quester, George, ed., Nuclear Proliferation: Breaking the Chain (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1981)Google Scholar; and Brenner, Michael, Nuclear Power and Non-Proliferation (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1981)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

51. On the Reagan approach to non-proliferation, which stresses “reliable supply,” see Clausen, Peter, “The Reagan Non-Proliferation Policy,” Arms Control Today 14 (12 1982)Google Scholar; Spector, “Unfinished Business”; and Dunn, “Standing up for the NPT.”

52. Walker, William and Lonnroth, Mans, Nuclear Power Struggles: Industrial Competition and Proliferation Control (London: George Allen and Unwin, 1983), p. 1Google Scholar.

53. Pilat, Joseph F., “The Future of the Nuclear Supply Regime,” in Jones, , Institutional Policy Choices, pp. 9091Google Scholar.

54. For example, see Keohane, After Hegemony, passim; Krasner, International Regimes, passim; and the special issue of World Politics 38 (10 1985)Google Scholar, entitled “Cooperation under Anarchy.”

55. Axelrod, and Keohane, , “Achieving Cooperation under Anarchy,” p. 226Google Scholar.

56. The principal author of the functional theory is Robert Keohane; see his “Demand for International Regimes,” passim; and After Hegemony, pp. 85–109. For a related argument, see Stein, Arthur A., “Coordination and Collaboration; Regimes in an Anarchic World,” in Krasner, , International Regimes, pp. 115140Google Scholar.

57. Keohane, , After Hegemony, p. 88Google Scholar.

58. Ibid., p. 89.

59. Ibid., p. 91.

60. Ibid., p. 94.

61. See Waltz, Kenneth N., Theory of International Politics (New York: Random House, 1979), pp. 3859Google Scholar.

62. Krasner, , “Structural Causes,” p. 1Google Scholar.

63. Keohane acknowledges that “cooperation need not involve any negotiation at all,” but focuses his attention exclusively on “coordination achieved through bargaining,” After Hegemony, p. 76.

64. See Young, Oran R., “Regime Dynamics: The Rise and Fall of International Regimes,” in Krasner, , International Regimes, pp. 93113Google Scholar.

65. Keohane, , After Hegemony, p. 46Google Scholar.

66. Ibid., p. 64.

67. Ibid., p. 27.

68. Haas, , “Why Collaborate?” pp. 367–68Google Scholar.

69. Haas, Ernst B., “Words Can Hurt You; or Who Said What to Whom about Regimes,” in Krasner, , International Regimes, pp. 2359Google Scholar.

70. Rosenau, , “Before Cooperation,” p. 864Google Scholar.

71. Ibid.

72. See Young, , “Regime Dynamics”; and Puchala, Donald J. and Hopkins, Raymond F., “International Regimes: Lessons from Inductive Analysis,” in Krasner, , International Regimes, pp.61–92Google Scholar.

73. Haas, , “Issue Linkage,” p. 372Google Scholar; the “tactical linkage” of issues is used only to obtain additional bargaining leverage, usually after a regime is formed.

74. Keohane, “Reciprocity,” passim.

75. The attempt to construct a complex interdependence model is the subject of a special issue of International Organization (Summer 1971), entitled “Transnational Relations and World Politics” and edited by Robert Keohane and Joseph Nye; and Keohane and Nye, Power and Interdependence.

76. See Waltz, , Theory of International Politics, and Keohane, Robert O., ed., Neorealism and Its Critics (New York: Columbia University Press, 1986)Google Scholar.

77. See Holsti, K. J., The Dividing Discipline: Hegemony and Diversity in International Theory (London: Allen and Unwin, 1985)Google Scholar.

78. Keohane, and Nye, , Power and Interdependence, p. 35Google Scholar.

79. Keohane, , After Hegemony, p. 83Google Scholar.

80. Keohane, and Nye, , Power and Interdependence, pp. 33–34Google Scholar.

81. Keohane, , “Demand for International Regimes,” p. 144Google Scholar.

82. Rosenau, , “Before Cooperation,” p. 877Google Scholar.

83. Snidal, Duncan, “The Game Theory of International Politics,” World Politics 38 (10 1985), p. 56CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

84. Richard L. O'Meara, “Regimes and Their Implications for International Theory,” Millennium: Journal of International Studies (Winter 1984), p. 256Google Scholar.

85. Krasner, Stephen D., “Regimes and the Limits of Realism,” in Krasner, , International Regimes, p. 368Google Scholar. While Keohane devotes little attention to exploring the role of knowledge and learning in regimes, he is well aware of its potential importance, Keohane, , After Hegemony, p. 132Google Scholar.

86. Young, Oran R., “International Regimes: Problems of Concept Formation,” World Politics 33 (04 1980), p. 31Google Scholar.

87. Puchala, and Hopkins, , in Krasner, , International Regimes, p. 63Google Scholar.

88. Young, , “Problems of Concept Formation,” p. 349Google Scholar.

89. See Puchala, and Hopkins's, discussion of “evolutionary change” in regimes, which occurs without major changes in the distribution of power, in “Lessons from Inductive Analysis,” pp. 6566Google Scholar.

90. Young, , “Regime Dynamics,” p. 93Google Scholar.

91. Puchala, and Hopkins, , “Lessons from Inductive Analysis,” p. 63Google Scholar.

92. See Kitschelt, Herbert, “Four Theories of Public Policy Making and Fast Breeder Reactor Development,” International Organization 40 (Winter 1986), pp. 65105CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

93. Steinbruner, John D., The Cybernetric Theory of Decision: New Dimensions of Political Analysis (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1974)Google Scholar.