Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-jr42d Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-19T01:23:31.461Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

World Market, State, and Family Farm: Social Bases of Household Production in the Era of Wage Labor

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  03 June 2009

Harriet Friedmann
Affiliation:
University of Toronto

Extract

Between 1873 and 1935 dramatic changes took place in the character of production in the industrial nations of the world. Longstanding and newly formed states in Europe and America engaged in vigorous campaigns of territorial expansion, so that virtually all the globe came to be incorporated within the sphere of world markets. During the same period, the expansion in industrial countries of new techniques of mass production coincided with growth and consolidation of organizations of people who worked for wages. The expansion of world markets, the development of mass produc— tion, and the new social importance of wage laborers, while certainly not the only features of the era, are often viewed as its central, interrelated, and dynamic basis.1 In this context, the transformations of production which accompanied the rise of a world wheat market during these decades were quite unusual.

Type
Land, Markets, and Social Structure
Copyright
Copyright © Society for the Comparative Study of Society and History 1978

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

A draft of this paper was presented at the meetings of the American Sociological Association, September 1977. I received helpful criticisms of the draft from Jonathan Cohen, Paul David, John Eatwell, S. Rugumisa, Jack Wayne, and Jonathan Zeitlin. An earlier version of the analysis benefited from suggestion by Karen Anderson, Barry Edginton, George Homans, Nancy Howell, Michael Mann, Theda Skocpol, David Stark, Harrison White, and Gavin Wright.

1 See the comprehensive statement, from the point of view of the development of the productive forces of European nations, by Landes, David S., The Unbound Prometheus (Cambridge: The University Press, 1972), pp. 231–49Google Scholar. Mandel, Ernest, in Late Capitalism (London: New Left Books, 1975), Chs. 4 and 5, gives one of the possible Marxist accounts of the importance and relationships among these factors.Google Scholar

2 Friedmann, H.B., The Transformation of Wheat Production in the Era of the World Market, 1873–1935’ (unpublished Ph.D. thesis, Harvard University, 1976), p. 99.Google Scholar

3 Malenbaum, Wilfred, The World Wheat Economy 1885–1939 (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1953), pp. 236–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

4 Farnsworth, Helen C., ‘Decline and Recovery of Wheat Prices in the 'Nineties,’ Wheat Studies, 10:8 and 9 (1934), 293–94Google Scholar. The development of the triple expansion steam engine was of particular importance on the 1890s. For the prior period see Graham, G. S., ‘The Ascendancy of the Sailing Ship, 1850–85’, Economic History Review, ser. 2, IX (1954), 7488.Google Scholar

5 For data and analysis of the rise of a world wheat market and the two price falls, see Friedmann, , op. cit., Ch.2.Google Scholar

6 Ashley, William, ‘The Place of Rye in the History of English Food,’ The Economic Journal, 31 (1921). 285308.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

7 Some households producing wheat as a cash (or rent) crop at the outset of the period reverted to subsistence production during the period. This reversion is a separate question from the relation between capitalist and household commodity producers. See Friedmann, op. cit., especially Chs. 1 and 6.

8 Calculated from data in Malenbaum, , op. cit., pp. 238–39Google Scholar. An excellent history of Argentine wheat production is Scobie, James R., Revolution on the Pampas, A Social History of Argentine Wheat, 1860–1910 (Austin: University of Texas Press, 1964). This combination of capitalist and household wheat production within the national economy also characterized Germany and Hungary.Google Scholar

9 The growth of tenancy has been an important theme in the historiography of American agriculture largely because of its incompatibility with the goals of much public land policy. The implied loss of independence is not to be underestimated, but it does not affect the fundamentally different relations to the means of production of households from that of people who sell their labor power on the market. The possibility of comparable advantages existing for simple commodity producers is suggested by Gates, Paul W., Landlords and Tenants on the Prairie Frontier. Studies in American Land Policy (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1973), pp. 255–58, 298301Google Scholar. For the general question of tenancy in America, see Bogue, Allan G., From Prairie to Cornbelt: Farming on the Illinois and Iowa Prairies in the Nineteenth Century (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1963), Ch. IIIGoogle Scholar; Shannon, Fred A., The Farmer's Last Frontier. Agriculture, 1860–1897 (New York and Toronto: Farrar & Rinehart, Inc., 1945) passim, esp. pp. 161, 418Google Scholar; Gates, Paul W., Fifty Million Acres: Conflicts over Kansas Land Policy, 1854–1890 (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1954), pp. 230–94Google Scholar; Danhof, Clarence H., Change in Agriculture: The Northern United States, 1820–1870 (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1969), pp. 8893.Google Scholar

10 These comments apply to commercial forms of production only. The relation to, for example, feudal rent, is beyond the scope of this essay.

11 The important wheat exports from India in the late nineteenth century were from new settlers on government organized lands. Many of them gained title during the period of expanding exports. See Wright, Conrad P. and Davis, J.S., ‘India as a Producer and Exporter of Wheat,’ Wheal Studies, 111:8 (1927), 317412.Google Scholar

12 In addition to the examples mentioned in this paragraph, the most important instance is the dependency school, and its more comprehensive variant, the world-system approach. For the former, see Frank, Andre Gunder, Latin America, Underdevelopment or Revolution (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1969)Google Scholar, and for the latter see Wallerstein, Immanuel, The Modern World-System. Capitalist Agriculture and the Origins of the European World-Economy in the Sixteenth Century (New York: Academic Press, 1974)Google Scholar and by the same author, The Rise and Demise of the World Capitalist System,’ Comparative Studies in Society and History, 16:4 (1974), 387–15.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

13 Johnson, Arthur H., The Disappearance of the Small Landowner (1909), reprinted by Oxford University Press, 1963CrossRefGoogle Scholar, a classic of English agricultural history, explains the decline of small landowners (usually called ‘peasants’) through the growth of commercial agriculture in the sixteenth century. Small holders, as I attempt to show here and elsewhere (Friedmann, , op. cit.), are not survivors in any sense from the sixteenth century, but a new kind of household producer, a specialized commodity producer.Google Scholar

14 Given the wide empirical variation, and the lack of agreed and consistent analytical definition of ‘peasants’, I shall avoid using the term except when used by others in specific instances. Some attempts to characterize peasantries generally are, e.g., Wolf, Eric, Peasants (Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall, 1966)Google Scholar and Shanin, Teodor, ‘The Peasantry as a Political Factor,’ reprinted in Shanin, T., The Awkward Class, Political Sociology of Peasantry in a Developing Society, Russia 1910–25 (London: Oxford University Press, 1972)Google Scholar. For a critique of the concept, see Ennew, Judith, Hirst, Paul, and Tribe, Keith, ‘“Peasantry” as an Economic Category,’ The Journal of Peasant Studies, 4:4 (1977), 295322.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

15 Wolf, Eric, ‘Types of Latin American Peasantry: A Preliminary Discussion’. American Anthropologist, 57:3 (1955), p. 454.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

16 Hill, Polly, Migrant Cocoa-Farmers of Southern Ghana (Cambridge: The University Press, 1963).Google Scholar

17 The linguistic identification of commodity and capitalist production is reinforced by neo-classical economics, which focuses on the motivations of producers and their responses to constraints of various sorts. Therefore, the importance of the internal structure of ‘enterprises’ lies primarily in mediating the quantitatively conceived responses of producers. Qualitative differences in the organization of production, such as family or hired labor, imply the necessity for structural categories in cases where different producers are equally subject to market pressures.

18 See the leading historian of recent European agriculture, Dovring, Folke, Land and Labor in Europe 1900–1950 (The Hague: Martinus Nijhoff, 1965)Google Scholar and ‘The Transformation of European Agriculture,’ in Habakkuk, H. J. and Postan, M., eds., The Cambridge Economic History of Europe (Cambridge: The University Press, 1965), Vol. VI, Pt. II.Google Scholar

19 Weber, Max, ‘Capitalism and Rural Society in Germany,’ in Gerth, H. and Mills, C. W., eds., From Max Weber (New York: Oxford University Press, 1958), p. 382Google Scholar

20 Sargent, F. L., ‘From Feudalism to Family Farms in France’, Agricultural History, XXV:4 (1961), 198–99.Google Scholar

21 Calculated from data in A Century of Agricultural Statistics, Great Britain, 1866–1966,’ (Her Majesty's Stationery Office, 1968), p. 19Google Scholar

22 Shollenberger, J. H., Wheat Requirements in Europe, United States Department of Agriculture Technical Bulletin No. 535 (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1935).Google Scholar

23 David, Paul A., ‘The Landscape and the Machine: Technical Interrelatedness, Land Tenure, and the Mechanization of the Corn Harvest in Victorian Britain,’ in McCloskey, Donald N., ed., Essays on a Mature Economy, Britain After 1840 (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1971), p. 148.Google Scholar

24 ‘The Solidarity of Occupational Groups,’ in Parsons, T., Shils, E., Naegele, K. D., and Pitts, J. R., eds., Theories of Society, Vol. I (New York: The Free Press, 1961), p. 359.Google Scholar

25 The Social Organization of Production,’ in Parsons, , et al. , op. cit., pp. 468–69.Google Scholar

26 For example, in Capital (New York: International Publishers, 1967), Vol. III, p. 334, Marx observed that pre-capitalist production sometimes involves economies which allow it to ‘put up a stubborn resistance to the products of the big industries.’Google Scholar

27 While Marx himself was not entirely explicit or consistent on these questions, which were largely marginal to his central concerns, certain of his followers have addressed them directly. See Lenin, V. I., in The Development of Capitalism in Russia (Moscow: Institute of Marxism-Leninism, 1957)Google Scholar and The Agrarian Question and the Critics of Marx (Moscow: Progress Publishers, 1976)Google Scholar; Kautsky, Karl in Banaji, J., trans., ‘Summary of Selected Parts of Kautsky's The Agrarian Question,’ Economy and Society, 5:1 (1976), 249.Google Scholar

28 This definition excludes subsistence plots which function as a supplement to a wage which in itself would not allow for the reproduction of a working class. The most widely known instance is South Africa, discussed by Michael Burawoy, The Functions and Reproduction of Migrant Labor: Comparative Material from Southern Africa and the United Slates,’ American Journal of Sociology, 81:5 (1976), 1051–87Google Scholar, and by Wolpe, Harold, ‘Capitalism and Cheap Labour-Power in South Africa: From Segregation to Apartheid,’ Economy and Society, 4:1 (1972), 425–56CrossRefGoogle Scholar. It also characterizes the hacienda system in Latin America; see Wolf, Eric R., ‘The Hacienda System and Agricultural Classes in San Jose, Puerto Rico,’ in Béteille, André, ed.. Social Inequality (Harmonsworth, England: Penguin, 1969), 172–90.Google Scholar

29 In the school of Marxism following Louis Althusser, ‘social formation’ is the term used for historical ‘social wholes’ (see Poulantzas, N., Political Power and Social Classes (London: New Left Books, 1973), p. 15) in contrast to analytical abstractions such as the mode of production. It is meant to identify what social scientists usually mean by a ‘society.’Google Scholar

30 The most direct, if not unproblematic, statement of this position is from Marx himself, in his preface to A Contribution to the Critique of Political Economy (New York: International Publishers, 1970)Google Scholar. The term can be interpreted to refer to the ‘economic foundations’ only, but this reading leaves the ‘superstructure’ hanging in an analytical void. One need not have exact ‘correspondence’ between the ‘levels’ of a social formation, much less simple determination of one by the other, to appreciate the necessity of an analytical basis (beyond the supposedly ‘concrete’ categories of ‘social structure’ or ‘social formation’) for incorporating both and their mutual relations. See Foster-Carter, A., ‘The Modes of Production Controversy, New Left Review, 107 (1978), 73:1Google Scholar. Cf. Althusser, Louis and Balibar, Etienne, Reading Capital (London: New Left Books, 1975), pp. 42, 216–24Google Scholar, and Hindess, Barry and Hirst, Paul Q., Pre-Capitalist Modes of Production (London: Routledge and Kegan Paul, 1975), pp. 1317.Google Scholar

31 See Althusser, and Balibar, , op. cit.Google Scholar, and Hindess, and Hirst, , op. cit.Google Scholar

32 Foster-Carter, A., op. cit., p. 76.Google Scholar

33 As Foster-Carter, ibid., p. 74, argues, to allow any empirical variation to define a new mode produces ‘inevitable inflation and debasement of the coinage: each Andean valley has its own mode of production, and individuals may change them two or three times a week like underwear.’

34 Commodity production is a relation in itself. Simple commodity production is like most subsistence production in its household basis of organization (though not in the extent of kin ties included within the household), but differs from it in being tied completely to other commodity producers through the market. In the latter set of social relations, simple commodity production is like capitalist production, and for this reason, they must share the range of productive techniques, which in conjunction with local conditions can generate production within the enforced range of labor productivity, if both are to survive.

35 This usage more or less follows Marx. The term personal consumption replaces the more usual individual consumption. These categories are, moreover, consistent with Wolfs distinction between ‘replacement fund’ (encompassing personal and productive consumption) and ‘surplus.’ See his Peasants, pp. 610.Google Scholar

36 This assumption is justified by considerable research in industrial sociology, which shows that workers with any hope, however unrealistic, of independent household production (generally agricultural) see themselves and participate in the labor process differently from those without. More than 30 years ago, Collins, Orvis, Dalton, Melville, and Roy, Donald, in ‘Restriction of Output and Social Cleavage in Industry,’ Journal of Applied Anthropology, 5:3 (1946), 114Google Scholar, argued that the worker identified with normal work practices hostile to management only when he came to believe ‘that his “station” in life ha[d] become fixed’ (p. 14). Workers who identified with management were often from farm backgrounds and retained a sense of property ownership even when it was no longer realistic. More recently Bernoux, Philippe, in ‘Les O.S. face à l'organisation industrielle,‘ Sociologie du Travail, 4 (1972), 410–36CrossRefGoogle Scholar, characterized differences among workers in a factory as ‘peasant culture’ and ‘worker culture.’ In this case the former understood their lack of relation to the capitalist enterprise, but in the context of dreaming of a return to independent production, however futile the hope (414–16). Finally, in a most interesting recent article, Hartmut Neuendorff and Charles Sabel have argued that whatever their objective relation to peasant production, certain workers have a specific ‘interpretive model’ for understanding their mode of life and labor which derives from their self-definition itself rooted ‘in the world of the peasant.’ In Modèles d'interpretation et categories du marche du travail,’ Sociologie du travail (1978:1), 6162. I am grateful to Jonathan Zeitlin for suggesting this argument and providing the references.Google Scholar

37 One instance of the latter situation is described by Marx, in Capital, Vol. I, pp. 278–97.Google Scholar

38 See ibid., Vol. Ill, pp. 142–99.

39 See note 36. Specific conditions of skill, seniority, and so on, which affect the conditions of employment of individuals in modern enterprises, are the result of organizational struggles and technical developments over the past century and a half. Agriculture has not shared fully in these developments, though they have not, as we shall see below, been entirely absent. The remnants of capitalist relations in English wheat farming today show limitations on this instrumentalism, but these seem to derive from a combination of the legacy of extreme exploitation during the 1930s and the enforced personalism of those who remained behind in a small village. See Blythe, Ronald, Akenfield (Penguin, 1972) for a vivid ‘portrait of an English village’ in the arable region of East Anglia.Google Scholar

40 Thorner, D., Kerblay, B., Smith, R. E. F., eds., On the Theory of Peasant Economy (Homewood, Ill.: American Economic Association Translation Series, 1966).Google Scholar

41 Millar, J. R., ‘A Reformulation of A. V. Chayanov's Theory of the Peasant Economy,‘ Economic Development and Cultural Change, 18 (1970), 219–29.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

42 Cited in Kerblay, Basile, ‘Chayanov and the Theory of Peasantry as a Specific Type of Economy,’ in Shanin, T., Peasants and Peasant Societies (Penguin, 1971), p. 152.Google Scholar

43 Millar, , op. cit., p. 222.Google Scholar

44 Theories of Surplus Value (Moscow: Progress Publishers, 1963), Part I, pp. 407–08.Google Scholar

45 Ibid., p. 408. Cf. Brown, Beverley, ‘Natural and Social Division of Labour—Engels and the Domestic Labour Debate,’ m/f, 1 (1978), p. 42.Google Scholar

46 Chayanov focuses on both the labor and consumption aspects of household demography, as reflected in the consumer/producer ratio. This is more important for partial subsistence households in which personal consumption (and sometimes demands of surplus product) is a much larger proportion of the total product than productive consumption. For specialized commodity production households, the reverse is true, so that variations in the number of consumers in the household is of little importance, whereas the number of laborers required under conditions of competition is of fundamental importance.

47 See, for example, Easterlin, Richard A., ‘Population Change and Farm Settlement in the Northern United States,’ Journal of Economic History, 36 (1976), 6370CrossRefGoogle Scholar. and Hohenberg, Paul. ‘Change in Rural France in the Period of Industrialization, 1830–1914,’ Journal of Economic History, 30 (1972), 227.Google Scholar

48 See Bogue, Alan G., From Prairie to Cornbelt. Farming on the Illinois and Iowa Prairies in the Nineteenth Century (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1963), p. 185Google Scholar, for the nineteenth century. Contemporary cooperation has been described by Bennett, J. W., ‘Reciprocal Exchanges among North American Agricultural Operators,’ Southwestern Journal of Anthropology, 24 (1968)CrossRefGoogle Scholar, and Kohl, Seena. Working Together (Toronto: Holt, Rinehart and Winston. 1976), pp. 4243.Google Scholar

49 As argued above, a surplus product may be required in the form of rent, taxes, etc., depending upon conditions within the social formation, but it is not inherent in the form of household production itself.

50 See note 36. That this is the real alternative to failure for commercial agricultural households is generally acknowledged. See, for example, Hedley, Max J., ‘Independent Commodity Production and the Dynamics of Tradition,’ Canadian Review of Sociology and Anthropology, 13:4 (1976), 413–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

51 Shanon, , op.cit., pp. 134–35.Google Scholar

52 Danhof, , op. cit., pp. 224–26.Google Scholar

53 Yerkes, Arnold P. and Church, L. M., ‘Cost of Harvesting Wheat by Different Methods,’ United States Department of Agriculture Bulletin No. 627 (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1918), write: ‘Of late years the smaller outfits [combines of 7 or 9 foot widths] have been increasing in number very rapidly’ (p. 19) and ‘… it may be pertinent to state that the seven and nine-foot outfits are, for the most part, individually owned and are used only on the farm of the owner, while the larger rigs are in many cases used more or less for custom work’ (p. 21).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

54 At least as this was reflected in the inadequacy of initial homestead allotments. See Webb, Walter Prescott, The Great Plains (New York: Grossett and Dunlap, 1931).Google Scholar

55 United States Department of Agriculture Yearbook (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1935).Google Scholar

56 United States Bureau of the Census, Historical Statistics of the United States, Colonial Times to 1957 (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office, 1960), p. 281.Google Scholar

57 For analysis of the relative importance of regional specialization and mechanization, see Parker, William N. and Klein, Judith V., ‘Productivity Growth in Grain Production in the United States, 1840–60 and 1900–10,’ in National Bureau of Economic research, Output, Employment, and Productivity in the United States after 1800, Studies in Income and Wealth, Vol. 30 (New York: Columbia University Press, 1966)Google Scholar; and Fisher, Franklin M. and Temin, Peter, ‘Regional Specialization and the Supply of Wheat in the United States, 1867–1914,’ Review of Economics and Statistics, 52 (1970), 134–49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

58 Historical Statistics of the United States, p. 281.Google Scholar

59 See the volume on Agriculture of the 1880 Census, pp. 529–30.Google Scholar

60 Shannon, , op cit., p. 144, writes: ‘…in the day of the sickle and flail, the farmer was limited to the amount of the grain he could reap, or about 7½ acres for each mower. But, in the 1890s, he might well grow 135 acres, if he wanted to specialize to that extent.‘Google Scholar

61 Calculated from data in Tostlebe, Alvin S., Capital in Agriculture: Its Formation and Financing Since 1870, National Bureau of Economic Research (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1957), pp.51 and 68.Google Scholar

62 Yerkes, and Church, , op cit., p. 12.Google Scholar

64 Tostlebe, , op. cit., p. 87.Google Scholar

65 Calculated from Ibid., pp. 48 and 51.

66 In a rare case in which such detailed data were reported. 79.4 percent of the owners of family farms in Cass County, North Dakota, in 1920, were married, while most other occupations in this specialized wheat producing district were held by single men. The only other occupational category with any significant number of married men (17.1 percent) was the pool of permanent agricultural wage laborers, which provided only one quarter of all reported labor. Galpin, C. J. and Larson, V. B., Farm Population of Selected Counties, United States Bureau of the Census (Washington, DC: Government Printing Office, 1924), p. 150Google Scholar. For an analysis of the role of wage labor, see Friedman, H., ‘Simple Commodity Production and Wage Labour in the American Plains,’ The Journal of Peasant Studies, in press.Google Scholar

67 Respondents to agricultural censuses consistently report that women do not do agricul- tural labor. There exists scattered evidence to the contrary, but it remains impossible to fully penetrate the ideological conception of women's role. Any unreported participation of women, of course, reinforces the importance of household labor.

68 Yerkes, and Church, , op. cit., pp. 1921.Google Scholar

69 For the interaction among size of farms, labor costs, and machine method costs, in the adoption of mechanical threshers in an earlier period, see David, Paul A., ‘The Mechanization of Reaping in the Ante-Bellum Midwest,’ in his Technical Choice, Innovation, and Economic Growth. Essays on American and British Experience in the Nineteenth Century (Cambridge: The University Press, 1975).Google Scholar

70 From the point of view of the capitalist, of course, not of the laborer. The latter has rightly been emphasized, since wages rarely allowed for mobility up the ‘agricultural ladder’ to ownership or even tenancy. See Gates, , Landlord and Tenants, pp. 318–19. But from the point of view of capitalist reproduction, the wage bill looks quite different, especially when competition by simple commodity producers is technically possible and actually overwhelming.Google Scholar

71 While the price of wheat in England fell 42 percent between 1882 and 1896, the prices of such articles of personal consumption as wool, cotton, and wood, fell by about 37 percent, 21 percent, and 34 percent, respectively. See Page, William, Commerce and Industry (London: Constable and Co., 1919), pp. 219–23Google Scholar, and Brown, Michael Barratt, The Economics of Imperialism (Penguin, 1974), pp. 246–47.Google Scholar

72 For citation of the major studies, see Bowman, John D. and Keehn, Richard H., ‘Agricultural Terms of Trade in Four Midwestern States,’ Journal of Economic History, 34 (1974), 593, n. 4CrossRefGoogle Scholar. See also Mayhew, Anne, ‘A Reappraisal of the Causes of Farm Protest in the United States, 1870–1900,’ Journal of Economic History, 30 (1972), 464–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

73 See note 66.

74 United States Department of Agriculture Yearbook, 1935.Google Scholar

75 Hedley, , op. cit.Google Scholar

76 Ibid.; Shannon, , op.cit., p. 303Google Scholar. For a detailed account of standards of living of Saskatchewan farm households in the 1930s, see Britnell, G. E., The Wheat Economy (Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1939), Ch. VIIGoogle Scholar. See also Hine, Robert V., The American West, An Interpretive History (Little, Brown & Co., 1973), p. 166.Google Scholar

77 Shannon, , op. cit., pp. 169172Google Scholar. Brogan, D. W., ‘The Rise and Decline of the American Agricultural Interest,’ Economic History Review, V:2 (1935), 1314Google Scholar. Waines, W. J., ‘Problems of the Drought Area in Western Canada,’ in Innes, H. A., ed., Essays in Political Economy (Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1938), pp. 205–9Google Scholar. European households which survived as commercial wheat producers under government protection were forced by land scarcity to practice better, as well as more intensive methods. See Shollenberger, , op. cit.Google Scholar

78 Gates, , Landlords and Tenants, pp. 253–59, 266–83.Google Scholar

79 Ibid., pp. 238–0. Shannon, , op. cit., p. 154.Google Scholar

80 Tostlebe, , op. cit., p. 169.Google Scholar

81 Ibid., p. 225. In 1910, almost two-thirds of farm mortgage debt was held by individuals, and less than one quarter by banks and insurance companies. By 1925, the respective proportions were 37.1 percent and 45.9 percent.

82 Ibid. At its peak in 1934, government credit accounted for 82.3 percent of existing farm mortgages in the American plains.

83 See North, Douglass C., ‘International Capital Flows and the Development of the American West,’ in Scheiber, Harry N., ed., United States Economic History (New York: Alfred A. Knopf, 1964).Google Scholar

84 Gates, , Fifty Million Acres, p. 253, points out the ambivalent position of railroads as carriers of freight and as land companies.Google Scholar

85 Webb, Walter Prescott, The Great Plains, pp. 295374.Google Scholar

86 Macdonald, Norman, Canada. Immigration and Colonization, 1941–1903 (Toronto: Macmillan, 1970).Google Scholar

87 Mayhew, , op. cit.Google Scholar

88 Macdonald, , op. cit., pp. 235–37Google Scholar. Bogue, Allan G., ‘The Land Mortgage Company in the Early Plains States,’ Agricultural History, XXV: 1 (1951), 2033Google Scholar; Clements, Roger V., ‘British-Controlled Enterprise in the West between 1870 and 1900, and Some Agrarian Reactions,’ Agricultural History, XXVII: 4 (1953), 132141Google Scholar; Greever, William S., ‘A Comparison of Railroad Land-Grant Policies,’ Agricultural History, XXV: 2 (1951), 8399Google Scholar. Easterbrook, W. T., Farm Credit in Canada (Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1938), pp. 4547.Google Scholar

89 Australia and Argentina present interesting comparisons. Despite the existence of large unsettled land areas, the social organization of the land, and the related availability of credit, favored very large, capitalist cattle and sheep ranchers relative to household wheat producers, an important factor in the comparative lack of growth of Argentine and Australian wheat production. See Scobie, , op. cit.Google Scholar; Ferns, H. S., Britain and Argentina in the Nineteenth Century (Oxford: The Clarendon Press, 1960), pp. 370–22Google Scholar; Clapham, J. H., The Bank of England. A History, Vol. II, 1797–1914 (Cambridge: The University Press, 1958), pp. 326–28Google Scholar; Friedmann, , op. cit., pp. 177210Google Scholar; Clark, Manning, A Short History of Australia (New York: The New American Library, 1969), pp. 140–47Google Scholar; Crowley, F. K., Australia's Western Third (London: Macmillan, 1960), p. 104Google Scholar. In both countries capitalist livestock production and for the most part simple commodity wheat production grew up in complex mutual relationship, in which the former generally had the economic and political advantage. The important shift in Australia came with the development of government credit to wheat producers in the 1890s. See Malenbaum, , op.cit., p. 142.Google Scholar

90 Dovring, , Land and Labor, pp. 192215Google Scholar; Tracy, Michael, Agriculture in Western Europe: Crisis and Adaptation Since 1880 (London: Jonathan Cape, 1964).Google Scholar

91 Orwin, C. S. and Whetham, E. H., History of British Agriculture 1846–1914 (London: Archon Books, 1964), pp. 251–68, esp. p. 259.Google Scholar

92 See especially the classic article by Kindleberger, C. P., ‘Group Behavior and International Trade,’ Journal of Political Economy, 59 (1951), pp. 3046CrossRefGoogle Scholar

93 Tracy, , op. cit., pp. 117221.Google Scholar

94 Gates, , Landlords and Tenants, pp. 249–66Google Scholar. Shannon, , op.cit., p. 156Google Scholar

95 Since the main concern of the census was to determine patterns of tenancy and owner- ship, paid employment was not given rigorous attention. Tenant and laborer status were often confused, and until the 1920 Census, nominal wages to inheriting children, and actual wages for farms sons temporarily employed elsewhere, were not distinguished from wages paid to fully proletarian laborers. See Gates' discussion in Landlords and Tenants, p. 305.Google Scholar

96 Ibid., p. 304.

91 Ibid., pp. 311–12.

92 Shannon, , op.cit., pp. 156–58.Google Scholar

99 Ibid., p. 159. Gates, , Landlords and Tenants, pp. 318–19.Google Scholar

100 Hedges, James B., ‘The Colonization Work of the Northern Pacific Railroad,’ Mississippi Valley Historical Review, XIII:3 (1926).Google Scholar

101 This wis prior to the convergence which marked the emergence of a world market in the mid-1880s. Although British prices were falling, the American wheat price, with the exception of one year, whowed a ‘steady advance’ from 1875 to 1882. Veblen, Thorsten, ‘The Price of Wheat Sine 867,’ Journal of Political Economy, I (18921893), 78.Google Scholar

102 Shannon, , op. cit., pp. 156–58.Google Scholar

103 Ibid., pp. 159–61.

104 Sargent, , op. cit., pp. 198–99.Google Scholar

105 Malenbaum, , op. cit., pp. 236–39.Google Scholar

106 Gerschenkron, Alexander, Bread and Democracy in Germany (Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press, 1943), p. 43.Google Scholar

107 See ibid., passim for a brilliant analysis of the effects on German politics of the agrarian structures and policies of the Junker class.

108 Gerschenkron uses 100 acres as a lower limit. Ibid., p. 22 He gives the quotation from Weber on p. 45. Clapham, J. H. refers to Junker holdings as ‘perhaps 2,000’ acres. The Economic History of France and Germany 1815–1914 (Cambridge: The University Press, 1955), p. 200.Google Scholar

109 Tracy, , op. cit., p. 202.Google Scholar

110 Gerschenkron, , op. cit., pp. 91104.Google Scholar

111 For a brief account of this process, see Borchardt, Knut, ‘The Industrial Revolution in Germany, 1700–1914’, in Cipolla, Carlo M., ed., The Emergence of Industrial Societies, 1 (London: Collins/Fontana, 1973), pp. 9599.Google Scholar

112 Born, Karl Erich, ‘Structural Changes in German Social and Economic Development at the End of the Nineteenth Century,’ in Sheehan, James J., ed., Imperial Germany (New York and London: Franklin Watts, 1976), p. 34.Google Scholar

113 Walker, Mack, Germany and the Emigration 1816–1885 (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1964), pp. 184–90.Google Scholar

114 Rosenberg, Hans, ‘The Economic Impact of Imperial Germany, Agricultural Policy,’ Journal of Economic History, 23 (1943), p. 102.Google Scholar

115 Perren, Richard, ‘The Landlord and Agricultural Transformation, 1870–1900,’ Agricultural History Review, 18:1 (1970), 3651Google Scholar. Also Orwin and Whetham, , op. cit., p. 287.Google Scholar

116 Born, , op. cit., p. 22.Google Scholar

117 Gerschenkron, , op. cit., pp. 101–3.Google Scholar

118 Ibid., p.105

119 Landes, , op. cit., pp. 408–09.Google Scholar

120 Tracy, , op. cit., p. 209.Google Scholar

121 Gerschenkron, , op. cit., p. 79Google Scholar

122 Rosenberg, , op. cit., p. 105.Google Scholar

123 Gerschenkron, , op. cit.Google Scholar

124 Ibid., pp. 71–80.

125 Ibid., p.43.

126 Ibid., pp. 81–88. See also Ashley, , op. cit.Google Scholar

127 Gerschenkron, , op. cit., p. 71.Google Scholar

128 Ibid., pp.109, 117.

129 Ibid., p. 124.

130 Shollenberger, , op. cit., p. 83.Google Scholar

131 Borchardt, , op. cit., p. 125.Google Scholar

132 Dovring, , Land and Labor, p. 248.Google Scholar

133 E. Germany, like Eastern Europe generally, but unlike Western Europe, including W. Germany, showed a decrease in the number of hectares per male active in agriculture in 1950. Ibid., p. 66. This probably reflects increased intensity attendant upon the dismemberment of the large, unproductive estates of an anachronistic aristocracy.

134 Fairlie, Susan, ‘The Corn Laws and British Wheat Production, 1829–76,’ Economic History Review, 2nd ser., 22 (1969), 88116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

135 Jones, E. L., ‘The Agricultural Labour Market in England, 1793–1872,’ Economic History Review, 2nd ser., 17 (1964), 322.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

136 Ibid., p. 337.

137 Ibid., pp. 330–38.

138 Orwin, and Whetham, , op. cit., pp. 203–39.Google Scholar

139 Dunbabbin, J. P. D., ‘The Incidence and Organization of Agricultural Trades Unionism in the 1870s,’ Agricultural History Review, 16 (1968), 124–25.Google Scholar

140 Collins, E. J. T., ‘Harvest Technology and Labour Supply in Britain, 1790–1870,’ Economic History Review, ser. 2, 22 (1969), 453–73CrossRefGoogle Scholar. See also David, , ‘Landscape and Machine.’Google Scholar

141 Fletcher, T. W., ‘The Great Depression of English Agriculture, 1873–1896,’ Economic History Review, ser. 2, 13 (1960), 430–31Google Scholar. Also see Perry, P. J., British Farming During the Great Depression 1870–1914, An Historical Geography (Newton Abbot, Devon: David & Charles, 1974), pp. 102–07Google Scholar

142 Orwin, and Whetham, , op. cit., p. 345. This includes partial subsistence farms in all parts of Great Britain as well as fully commercial farms and thus somewhat overstates the case.Google Scholar

143 They managed some shift in the basis of their wealth, however. See Thompson, F. M. L., English Landed Society in the Nineteenth Century (London: Routledge & Regan Paul, 1963), pp. 302–03.Google Scholar

144 Fisher, J. R., ‘The Farmers' Alliance: An Agricultural Protest Movement of the 1880s,’ Agricultural History Review, 26:1 (1978), 1525Google Scholar. Also Orwin, and Whetham, , op. cit., pp. 298302.Google Scholar

145 Orwin, and Whetham, , op. cit., p. 248.Google Scholar

146 Ibid., pp. 264–66, 309–10.

147 An impressive innovator was George Baylis of Berkshire. After losing money on a farm of 240 acres with the traditional rotations, Baylis decided in 1866 to apply the findings of the Rothamsted experiments, using artificial fertilizers and adjusting his rotations to corn, fallow, and clover. His success generally was ignored. Orwin, and Whetham, , op. cit., p. 277.Google Scholar

148 Sheail, John, ‘Land Improvement and Reclamation: The Experiences of the First World War in England and Wales,’ Agricultural History Review, 24:2 (1976), pp. 110–12Google Scholar

149 Ibid., pp. 124–25.

150 Tracy, M. A., ‘Fifty Years of Agricultural Policy,’ Journal of Agricultural Economics, 27:3 (1976), pp. 336–37CrossRefGoogle Scholar

151 The number of tractors, for example, increased from very few in 1930 to over a hundred thousand in 1942. See ‘A Century of Agricultural Statistics,’ pp. 60, 71.Google Scholar

152 Long, W. Harwood, ‘The Development of Mechanization in English Farming,’ Agricultural History Review, 11 (1963), 21Google Scholar; Whetham, Edith H., ‘The Mechanisation of British Farming 1910–1945,’ Journal of Agricultural Economics. 21:3 (1970), 324–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

153 Whetham, , op. cit., pp. 322–23.Google Scholar

154 Long, , op. cit., p.26Google Scholar

155 Ibid.

156 Stanley, George F. G., The Birth of Western Canada. A History of the Riel Rebellions (Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1960), pp. 49, 107–25, 189.Google Scholar

157 Treadgold, D. W., The Great Siberian Migration (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1957).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

158 Malenbaum, , op. cit., pp. 236–37.Google Scholar

159 Rothstein, Morton, ‘America in the International Rivalry for the British Wheat Market, 1860–1914,’ reprinted in Scheiber, Harry N., ed., United States Economic History (New York: Alfred A. Knopf, 1964), p. 302.Google Scholar

160 Blain, Marc-A., ‘Le Role de la dependence externe et des structures sociales dans l'economie frumentaire du Canada et de l'Argentine (1880–1930),’ Revue d'Histoire de I'Amerique Francaise, 26:2 (1972), 239–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar