Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-xtgtn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-23T09:17:10.645Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Determinants of Innovation in Organizations*

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 August 2014

Lawrence B. Mohr*
Affiliation:
The University of Michigan

Extract

The present study is an attempt to identify the determinants of innovation in public agencies, i.e., the degree to which they adopt and emphasize programs that depart from traditional concerns. Innovation is suggested to be the function of an interaction among the motivation to innovate, the strength of obstacles against innovation, and the availability of resources for overcoming such obstacles.

The significance of the research can be viewed in terms of Hyneman's observation nearly twenty years ago that bureaucratic agencies “… may fail to take the initiative and supply the leadership that is required of them in view of their relation to particular sectors of public affairs. …” His concern was the responsiveness of the public sector not only to expressed wants but to public wants that may go unexpressed, or be only weakly expressed, and whose utility is much more easily recognized by the informed bureaucratic official than by the ordinary citizen.

While the results and conclusions to be reported appear to be largely valid for organizations in general, the empirical focus will be local departments of public health which, as a class, have had a rather dramatic succession of opportunities to respond to new public problems over the past twenty-five years. A brief introductory paragraph will orient the reader to the applied setting.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 1969

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

*

I wish to express my gratitude for valuable advice and comments from Robert Friedman, Irwin Rosenstock, Philip Converse, Ferrel Heady, M. Kent Jennings, Robert Northrop, and John Romani. Many of the ideas were sharpened and elaborated in discussions during the preparation of “Innovation in State and Local Bureaucracies,” by R. S. Friedman, L. B. Mohr and R. M. Northrop, a paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, New York, 1966. The research reported here was supported by the Public Health Service, Research Grant No. CH 00044 from the Division of Community Health Services.

References

1 Hyneman, Charles S., Bureaucracy in a Democracy (New York: Harper and Brothers, 1950), p. 26 Google Scholar.

2 For a much more recent treatment of bureaucratic innovation and public responsiveness, see Simon, Herbert A., “The Changing Theory and Changing Practice of Public Administration,” in Pool, Ithiel de Sola (ed.), Contemporary Political Science: Toward Empirical Theory (New York: McGraw-Hill Book Co., 1987), pp. 86120 Google Scholar. “The ‘power’ to innovate,” says Simon (p. 106), “… is probably the principal power of the bureaucracy in the realm of policy and value.”

3 Emerson, Haven, Local Health Units for the Nation: A Report (New York: The Commonwealth Fund, 1945), p. 2 Google Scholar.

4 See Thompson, Victor A., “Bureaucracy and Innovation,” Administrative Science Quarterly, 10 (06, 1965), p. 2 CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Rogers, Everett M., Diffusion of Innovation (New York: Free Press of Glencoe, 1962), p. 308 Google Scholar; Wilson, James Q., “Innovation in Organization: Notes Toward A Theory,” in Thompson, James D. (ed.), Approaches to Organizational Design (Pittsburgh: Univ. of Pittsburgh Press, 1966), p. 196 Google Scholar; Barnett, Homer G., Innovation (New York: McGraw-Hill Book Co., 1953), p. 7 Google Scholar.

5 The same general distinction has been made by others. Cf., Rogers, op. cit., pp. 195–196, and Simon, op. cit., p 107.

6 See Steiner, Gary A. (ed.), The Creative Organization (Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 1965), pp. 1618 Google Scholar.

7 Harold Guetzkow, “The Creative Person in Organizations,” in Steiner, op. cit., pp. 35–45; Burns, Tom and Stalker, G. M., The Management of Innovation (London: Tavistock Publications, 1961), pp. 85–86, 89, 121122 Google Scholar; Thompson, op. cit., p. 12.

8 Mansfield, Edwin, “The Speed of Response of Firms to New Techniques,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, (05, 1963), 293304 Google Scholar.

9 Mytinger, Robert E., Innovations in Public Health (unpublished doctoral dissertation, Univ. of California at Los Angles, 1965), p. 212 Google Scholar.

10 Hage, Jerald and Aiken, Michael, “Program Change and Organizational Properties: A Comparative Analysis,” American Journal of Sociology, 72 (03, 1967), pp. 516517 CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed.

11 Eisenstadt, Samuel N., The Political Systems of Empires (New York: The Free Press of Glencoe, 1963), pp. 27, 33112 Google Scholar.

12 Rogers, op. cit., pp. 40, 285–292.

13 Hage and Aiken, op. cit., pp. 503–519.

14 Zald, Mayer N. and Denton, Patricia, “From Evangelism to General Service: The Transformation of the YMCA,” Administrative Science Quarterly, VIII, No. 2 (09, 1963), p. 234 Google Scholar.

15 Burns and Stalker, op. cit., p. 96.

16 Rogers, op. cit., pp. 285–292.

17 Blau, Peter M., The Dynamics of Bureaucracy (2d ed. rev.; Chicago: Univ. of Chicago Press, 1963), p. 246 Google Scholar; Rogers, loc. cit.; Fliegel, Frederick C., “A Multiple Correlation Analysis of Factors Associated with Adoption of Farm Practices,” Rural Sociology, 21 (09-12, 1956), pp. 288–289, 291 Google Scholar; Rogers, Everett M., “A Conceptual Variable Analysis of Technological Change,” Rural Sociology, 23 (06, 1958), pp. 139–140, 143145 Google Scholar; Eisenstadt, loc. cit.

18 Merton, Robert K., Social Theory and Social Structure (Glencoe: The Free Press, 1949 and 1957), pp. 387420 Google Scholar; Gouldner, Alvin W., “Cosmopolitans and Locals: Toward an Analysis of Latent Social Roles,” Administrative Science Quarterly, II (12, 1957), pp. 281306 CrossRefGoogle Scholar, and (March, 1958), pp. 444–480.

19 Mytinger, op. cit., p. 195; Rogers, Diffusion of Innovation, op. cit., pp. 285–292.

20 Blau, op. cit., p. 246.

21 Rogers, loc. cit.

22 See Leavitt, Harold J., “Applied Organizational Change in Industry: Structural, Technical, and Human Approaches,” Handbook of Organizations, ed. March, James B. (Chicago: Rand McNally & Company, 1965), pp. 11441170 Google Scholar, for a valuable summary and critique.

23 Rogers, Diffusion of Innovation, op, cit., pp. 88–93.

24 See the introductory paragraphs, above, for examples of traditional and non-traditional programs. The primary sources for determining the precise composition of the two lists were An Official Declaration of Attitude of the American Public Health Association on Desirable Standard Minimum Functions and Suitable Organization of Health Activities,” American Journal of Public Health, 30 (09, 1940), 10991106 CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Mustard, Harry S., Government in Public Health (New York: The Commonwealth Fund, 1945), pp. 128, 140182 Google Scholar.

25 Cf., Mytinger's discussion of “barriers” to innovation. Mytinger, Robert E., “Barriers to Adoption of New Programs as Perceived by Local Health Officers,” Public Health Reports, 82 (02, 1967), 108114 CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed.

26 A significance level does not have the usual meaning here, since the group studied is a population rather than a probability sample. However, the test does provide some additional information about the strength of the reported relationship. It tells us the probability that a relationship this strong would appear if the group were divided into categories at random rather than according to actual scores on the independent variable. In light of these considerations, I have elected not to sprinkle significance levels throughout the report but to provide some bench marks that may be used as a guide by the interested reader: For N = 93, using a one-tailed test and the .05 level, the correlation r = .18 is significant; the comparable coefficients for other sample sizes in which we will be interested are r = .21 (for N = 69), r = .24 (for N = 49), and r = .30 for (N = 33).

27 Since the standard deviation of the ideology scores is greater than that of the activism scores (10.9 to 7.8), ideology contributes slightly more than activism to the summed index.

28 Separately, the correlation between activism and innovation, controlling for community size, is partial r = .32; for ideology and innovation, controlling for size, partial r = .29.

29 It will be of interest to note here how much innovation actually took place. Progressive programming ranged in these agencies from zero to 25.5 man-years, with a mean of 3.5 and a standard deviation of 4.9. Adoption, which will be considered in a moment, ranged from 2 programs to 27, with a mean of 11.7 and a standard deviation of 6.1.

30 r = −.17, a non-significant correlation.

31 Nor would it have been feasible to consider only post-1960 adoptions: such a procedure would have penalized the early adopters, many of whose innovations were made prior to 1960.

32 For example, one health officer had adopted 1 non-traditional program per year during 1960–1964 and had been in the job for 10 years. One might, therefore, reasonably estimate that 10 of the department's non-traditional programs are associated with his incumbency. Since this department had a total of 14 non-traditional programs it was not included in the subgroup. If its total had been 10 or less, it would have been included. If the health officer had been there for 15 years, the department would have been included regardless of total number of adoptions, for almost none of these programs had been introduced in local health departments before 1950.

33 The means for the whole group and for the subgroup, respectively, are: number of programs adopted, 11.7 and 11.2; population of jurisdiction, 110,000 and 109,000; 1959 expenditures, $188,000 and $165,000; activism-ideology, 119.9 and 120.1.

34 See Haefner, Don P., Kegeles, S. Stephen, Kirscht, John P., and Rosenstock, Irwin M., “Preventive Actions Concerning Dental Disease, Tuberculosis, and Cancer,” Public Health Reports, 82 (05, 1967), 451459 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

35 Wilson, James Q. and Banfield, Edward C., “Public-Regardingness as a Value Premise in Voting Behavior,” this Review 58 (12, 1964), 876887 Google Scholar.

36 The percent who completed two or more years of college may well have been a better measure for our purpose. Unfortunately, such information is not available from the normal central sources, such as the County and City Data Book published by the U.S. Bureau of the Census. It should definitely not be concluded on the basis of these correlations that aggregate education level has little or nothing to do with resistance to change in communities.

37 Extent of public health training was measured on a ten-point scale. The data were obtained through a self-administered questionnaire left with the supervisors at the time of the health-officer interview. It would have been far better to have obtained this information on all professional employees in the department, but turnover is such that very few in each department had been there from 1960 through 1964.

38 The correlation between community size and health department expenditures is r = .88; between expenditures and adoptions, r =.65; between size and adoption, r = .63.

39 See Blalock, Hubert M. Jr., Causal Inference in Nonexperimental Research (Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1961), pp. 8391 Google Scholar.

40 Simon, Herbert A., “Comment: Firm Size and Rate of Growth,” Journal of Political Economy 72 (02, 1964), p. 81 CrossRefGoogle Scholar. See also the articles by Mansfield and by Simon and Bonini cited there.

41 Cyert, Richard M. and March, James G., A Behavioral Theory of the Firm (Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice-Hall, 1963), pp. 278279 Google Scholar.

42 Adams, Walter and Dirlam, Joel B., “Big Steel, Invention, and Innovation,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 80 (05, 1966), 167189 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

43 Mansfield, op. cit. See also his, Technical Change and the Rate of Imitation,” Econometrica, 29 (1961), 741766 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

44 For an excellent methodology for evaluation of public programs, see Deniston, O. L., Rosenstock, I. M. and Getting, V. A., “Evaluation of Program Effectiveness,” Public Health Reports, 83 (04, 1968), 323335 CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed.

45 Blalock, Causal Inferences in Nonexperimental Research, op. cit., pp. 91–92. For other suggested treatments of multiplicative relationships, see Blalock, Hubert M. Jr., “Theory Building and the Statistical Concept of Interaction,” American Sociological Review, 30 (06, 1965), 374380 CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Coleman, James S., Introduction to Mathematical Sociology (New York: The Free Press of Glencoe, 1964), pp. 224235 Google Scholar; Russett, Bruce M., Alker, Hayward R. Jr., Deutsch, Karl W., and Lasswell, Harold D., World Handbook of Political and Social Indicators (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1964), pp. 322340 Google Scholar; Alker, Hayward R. Jr., Mathematics and Politics (New York: The Macmillan Company, 1965), pp. 108111 Google Scholar; Alker, Hayward R. Jr., “The Long Road to International Relations Theory: Problems of Statistical Nonadditivity,” World Politics, 18, (07, 1966), 639644 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

46 The resources term in the equation becomes, in this case, an obstacles-resources term. It was calculated by adding together the expenditures and percent white collar scores, after first weighting each with the appropriate partial slope from the regression of adoption on activism-ideology, expenditures, and percent white collar.

47 Blalock, “Theory Building and the Statistical Concept of Interaction,” op. cit., p. 375.

48 Atkinson, John W., “Motivational Determinants of Risk-Taking Behavior,” Psychological Review, 64 (1957), 359372 CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed. Atkinson actually uses two aspects of total inclination to act—basic psychological drive, such as the need for achievement, and incentive value attached to the object of the behavior in question. These are multiplied together and it is their product that is multiplied by the expectancy factor to obtain a prediction of behavior. The present study does not distinguish the basic drive from the incentive component of overall motivation; both are probably involved to a certain extent in motivation as measured here. Atkinson's article has most recently been reprinted (and also updated) in Atkinson, John W. and Feather, Norman T. (eds.), A Theory of Achievement Motivation (New York: John Wiley, 1966), ChapterGoogle Scholar I. See also Chapter II, “Notes Concerning the Generality of the Theory of Achievement Motivation,” by Atkinson and Chapter 20, “Review and Appraisal,” by Atkinson and Feather.

49 Palmore, Erdman B. and Hammond, Phillip E., “Interacting Factors in Juvenile Delinquency,” American Sociological Review, 29 (12, 1964), 848854 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

50 Blalock, “Theory Building and the Statistical Concept of Interaction,” op. cit., p. 379.

51 Merton, op cit., pp. 131–194. See especially, p. 140.

52 Harary, Frank, “Merton Revisited: A New Classification for Deviant Behavior,” American Sociological Review, 31 (10, 1966), 693697 CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed.